Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

1 Annex 11: Market failure in - broadcasting, Lecture notes of Economic Theory

Market failure definition. 1.2. Economic theory suggests that perfectly competitive markets deliver efficient outcomes that maximise social value.

Typology: Lecture notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 09/12/2022

anala
anala 🇺🇸

4.3

(14)

12 documents

1 / 6

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download 1 Annex 11: Market failure in - broadcasting and more Lecture notes Economic Theory in PDF only on Docsity! 1 Annex 11: Market failure in broadcasting 1.1 This annex builds on work done by Ofcom regarding market failure in a number of previous projects. In particular, we discussed the types of market failure that affect traditional public service broadcasting in the first Public Service Broadcasting Review. More recently, the Digital Dividend Review set out a framework for considering market failure with particular reference to the broader social value of some media and communications services. Market failure definition 1.2 Economic theory suggests that perfectly competitive markets deliver efficient outcomes that maximise social value. However, economists recognize that certain factors, such as the presence of market power, can prevent this. To describe the outcome where factors are present that stop the market working efficiently, economists use the term market failure. 1.3 Often, where a market is judged to fail, according to a specific test, there is the potential for government intervention to act to resolve the failure and improve welfare and efficiency. It is a standard tool for guiding government intervention in the economy, underlying policies such as environmental taxes and congestion charging. In such circumstances, a market failure can be defined as an inefficient outcome where the market does not exhaust all the possible gains from trade given individuals’ preferences and the costs involved. 1.4 Market failure is therefore about efficiency, and the definition of efficiency usually adopted is that no individual could be made better off without making at least one other person worse off. One example of inefficiency under this definition is where prices are set above costs thus deterring marginal consumers from purchasing even though they value the product more than its cost of production. 1.5 Economists have identified a number of specific causes of market failure, such as market power and externalities1, and intervention needs to be guided by a careful assessment of the specific factors involved. Inappropriate intervention may simply make matters worse. Most markets are imperfect according to a strict assessment, but are not subject to intervention for this reason. 1.6 The nature of the response to a market failure may also be complex, and there is a variety of tools available to intervene to address market failures. The appropriate approach will depend on the exact nature of the failure being addressed. 1.7 Broadcasting is an industry with many special characteristics and there are a number of reasons why a completely unregulated market may lead to market 1 An externality occurs when a transaction between two parties has an impact on a third party who is not involved. The transacting parties will typically not take this impact into account. An example is pollution. failures. Intervention in public service broadcasting has traditionally been the solution to these failures. Changing technology may eliminate some of these reasons for intervention, but some may remain and, indeed, new ones may emerge. This annex discusses some of these issues. 1.8 In the DDR2, we argued that when a market fails to maximise total value, this can indicate the presence of a market failure. Within the concept of total value there are two key elements of value. The first is private value, which is the value consumers and firms derive from their interaction in a market. The second is external value, which is value that results from services provided by a market but which is not fully reflected in the choices of consumers or firms. Example of external effects are network effects and broader social value, which captures value which we derive as citizens as a result of the availability and consumption of services which are important to society as a whole. In the DDR we identified the following sources of broader social value: • access and inclusion – for example value derived from universal access and facilitating access to public services; • quality of life – for example value derived from providing access to services which promote quality of life, perhaps by helping to support or promote work-life balance or family life; • belonging to a community – for example value derived from allowing people with similar interests to communicate or from participating in your local community; • educated citizens – for example value derived from services with educational content or child-oriented services; • cultural understanding – for example value derived from services which reflect and strengthen cultural identities or promote diversity and understanding of other cultures; • informed democracy – for example value from services which provide information which facilitates democratic debate; and • social bads – this can include negative value derived under any of the headings set out above 1.9 All of these broader social values can be captured within an economic framework of welfare analysis as they represent externalities. That is, they represent the preferences of citizens around the provision of a service to other members of society. These services produce value that is separate from an individual’s private value or their own consumption. As individuals do not take such values into account when making consumption decisions, it fits under the heading of externalities. 2 http://www.ofcom.org.uk/consult/condocs/ddr/ 1.19 In standard economic terminology, this can be described as a problem of information deficiency – i.e. lack of knowledge of the location of content - combined with an inability to judge the quality of the guidance provided by many online navigational tools4. Broader social value 1.20 The strongest remaining market failure case for public service broadcasting is around externalities, and the enduring presence of externalities in broadcasting is at the heart of any discussion of market failure in this area. Individuals recognise that there are social benefits to public service broadcasting and are willing to pay for these wider benefits. Deliberative research carried out for this review found that the majority of individuals support payment for public service broadcasting, even for parts they do not use. Human Capital’s study on the BBC licence fee came to a similar conclusion. 1.21 In interpreting the results of research such as this, it is important to bear in mind that the justification for the scale of the main instrument of intervention within broadcasting– the licence fee – does not rest solely on social or public considerations. While the licence fee provides a solution to externalities in broadcasting, the revenue it generates should not be judged according to the size of these market failures alone. This is because many individuals would be willing to pay for at least some of the BBC’s content for their own use and would do so in a market without intervention. As such a proportion of the BBC’s revenue from this source is more properly considered private value, although it is monetised by means of the licence fee rather than subscription, as this can be a more efficient funding mechanism in the presence of externalities such as broader social value, the realisation of which is negatively effected by the exclusion which can occur under alternative approaches to funding. Thus, in assessing the appropriate level of the licence fee, in a situation where that is the sole source of income, it is necessary to consider both the private and social value created. 1.22 Although this argument is framed in economic terms, these factors are at the heart of the citizenship-based rationale for intervention to support content with broader social value. The concept of a positive externality is an economics- based way of expressing the point that an individual’s viewing of content can have additional benefits for society as a whole, for instance through his or her engagement in the democratic process as a more educated citizen. The purposes and characteristics of public service content defined by Ofcom are intended to address these citizenship issues – and so address the problem that the market is unlikely to provide the full set of content and services that will maximise the benefit to society. Other rationales 1.23 The rationale for intervention in public service broadcasting does not rest exclusively on quantifiable, preference-led, market failures. For this reason, the broader decisions around the level and nature of public service broadcasting are political and taken within a broader context than expressed preferences alone. 4 Goods or services with the characteristic that quality cannot be judged even after consumption are known as credence goods. 1.24 We might discuss this with reference to a number of key concepts, for example the role of the public service broadcasting as a leader not a follower of public opinion, perhaps in relation to democratic engagement. Elsewhere a wide range of policy areas, such as environmental policy, healthcare or criminal justice are determined by calculations often independent of stated consumers preferences and willingness to pay. 1.25 Within an economic context, these rationales have been termed merit goods, where individuals are unable – for a variety of reasons – to recognise the real value to themselves from such decisions. Although at least potentially valid, attempting to quantify such an approach is likely to be very difficult, hence they have been mediated through the public policy and political decision- making process. 1.26 Intervention of this nature may be of several forms: it may ensure support for types of intervention that is not broadly supported, e.g., the specific activity needed to deliver impact in disengaged communities; equally, it may suggest a general will to support intervention beyond the level justified by classic market failure. Conclusion 1.27 These rationales are multiple and overlapping. In essence, rationales exist for intervention in the broadcasting market both relating to conventional market failure and also social and political rationales for intervention. 1.28 Many of the historical market failures identified in the first PSB review are diminishing in magnitude as a result of changes in the market. Whereas, previously, the structure of the market made a strong case for the intervention on that basis alone, this no longer applies in the digital and online markets. 1.29 However, some major market failures endure, the main ones being the non- rivalrous nature of broadcasting combined with high levels of externalities, such as the opportunity to create broader social value. In addition, the structure of the online market is far from perfect and (minor) market failures may exist in online markets. 1.30 Finally, we stress that market failure is far from the only rationale for intervention in broadcast markets. Wider questions of public and social policy have historically driven the decision to intervene, and will continue to do so.
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved