Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Competition and Market Power: Benefits and Indicators of Declining Competition, Lecture notes of Business

This document from the Council of Economic Advisers discusses the benefits of competition for consumers, workers, entrepreneurs, and small businesses, as well as the indicators of declining competition in the economy, including increasing industry concentration, higher rents for a few firms, and lower labor market mobility.

Typology: Lecture notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 09/27/2022

albertein
albertein 🇺🇸

4.8

(4)

6 documents

1 / 17

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download Competition and Market Power: Benefits and Indicators of Declining Competition and more Lecture notes Business in PDF only on Docsity! COU NCI L O F ECO NO MIC ADVI S ER S IS SU E BRI EF APRI L 2016 BENEFITS OF COMPETITION AND INDICATORS OF MARKET POWER Introduction This issue brief describes the ways in which competition between firms can benefit consumers, workers, entrepreneurs, small businesses and the economy more generally, and also describes how these benefits can be lost when competition is impaired by firms’ actions or government policies. Several indicators suggest that competition may be decreasing in many economic sectors, including the decades-long decline in new business formation and increases in industry-specific measures of concentration. Recent data also show that returns may have risen for the most profitable firms. To the extent that profit rates exceed firms’ cost of capital— which may be suggested by the rising spread on the return to invested capital relative to Treasury bonds— they may reflect economic rents, which are returns to the factors of production in excess of what would be necessary to keep them in operation. Such rents may divert resources from consumers, distort investment and employment decisions, and encourage firms to engage in wasteful rent-seeking activities. The causes underlying a possible decrease in competition and corresponding increase in market power are not clear, but candidate explanations include efficiencies associated with scale, increases in merger and acquisition activity, firms’ crowding out existing or potential competitors either deliberately or through innovation, and regulatory barriers to entry such as occupational licensing that have reduced the entry of new firms into a variety of markets. Government action can help reverse this trend. Antitrust authorities, namely the Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), are charged with enforcing antitrust laws, challenging anticompetitive mergers, anticompetitive exclusionary conduct, and collusion by competitors. Their enforcement actions can block consolidation that reduces competition in a market, 1 While in theory these benefits can accrue even when there are only a few firms or a single firm in the marketplace, provided that the monopolist faces a credible threat of entry by other firms (Spence 1977, sanction anticompetitive behavior, and help define the contours of antitrust law through court decisions. These measures not only have immediate effects on the behavior that is challenged but also may help deter anticompetitive abuses in the future. Promoting competition extends beyond enforcement of antitrust laws, it is also about a range of other pro- competitive policies. Several U.S. departments and agencies are actively using their authority to advance pro-competition and pro-consumer policies and regulations. For example, in several cases the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) of the Department of Transportation (DOT) has sought to provide competitive airline carriers with greater access to take-off and landing slots at capacity constrained “slot-controlled” airports. The Federal Communications Commission (FCC), in its most recent design of a spectrum auction, established a market-based spectrum reserve designed to ensure against excessive concentration in holdings of low-band spectrum. Other recent examples include government actions on cell phone unlocking, net neutrality, standards-essential patents, and defense acquisition and procurement. This brief argues that consumers and workers would benefit from additional policy actions by the government to promote competition within a variety of industries. In addition, more work is needed to understand how policies that promote competition should be applied in the digital economy and other technologically dynamic sectors. Benefits of Competition and Potential Harms from Market Power A long line of economic literature argues that competition among firms benefits consumers via lower prices (for an overview, see Kovacic and Shapiro (2000)).1 Dixit 1980), the benefits are more certain when there is vigorous competition among existing competitors. Tirole (1988) and Cabral (2000) provide useful overviews of the 2 Competition can benefit consumers in other ways as well: competition may lead to greater product variety, higher product quality, and greater innovation, which drives productivity growth and helps lift living standards (Hotelling 1929; Aghion et al. 2005; Shapiro 2012).2 When there is little or no competition, consumers are made worse off if a firm uses its market power to raise prices, lower quality for consumers, or block entry by entrepreneurs. A firm with market power recognizes that if it reduces price to gain more customers, it loses revenue on the existing customers it already has. Thus, it may set a higher price and provide a lower quantity of its product than would maximize societal welfare. Competition pushes firms to reduce price below this level, both to gain share from rivals, and in recognition that higher prices can be profitably undercut by competitors who are similarly trying to increase their sales. Alternatively, monopolists may choose not to upgrade quality or variety, which would also leave customers worse off than if the market had competitors. And monopolists may be less rigorous in pursuing efficient cost reductions, for as Sir John Hicks (1935) famously wrote, “the best of all monopoly profits is a quiet life.” Competition between firms may also help workers. In the same way that two firms might compete against one another and lower prices to entice consumers to purchase a product, firms competing to hire from a specialized labor market may raise wages to attract and retain workers. In addition, small businesses and entrepreneurs can benefit, for example, when upstream firms compete against each other for the opportunity to supply a product to a downstream small business or entrepreneur. If an entrepreneur sells its products to downstream firms rather than to end-users, it would benefit from there being a greater number of downstream firms to which it can sell products—the greater the number of downstream firms, the better the ability to negotiate a good price for the products it sells. Thus, whether the business model of an entrepreneur is business-to-business or business-to-consumer, competition among upstream firms and among downstream firms helps the entrepreneur grow his or theoretical conditions, assumptions, and extensions needed for these benefits to accrue. 2 The link between competition, innovation and productivity growth is covered in greater detail in her business by creating and capturing value in the marketplace (Brandenburger and Stuart 1996). A firm that has market power when purchasing inputs or hiring workers may be able to exploit its market power, at least in the short-run. “Monopsony power” in the labor market may lead a firm to restrict employment, reducing wages below what they would be in a competitive market. In the classic example of isolated “company towns” in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, workers only had one option to which to sell their labor and hence could be exploited by this company, at least in the short run. Boal (1995) finds some evidence of monopsony power in the short run on the part of coal mining firms that owned company towns in the early 1900s. But over the longer run, it appears that workers move to find better paying jobs if wages are too low. This dynamic highlights how the mobility of assets—be they human, capital, or even digital—may help to mitigate against market power. Firms can move from exercising their market power to the point where they are abusing it. Standard Oil at the turn of the previous century helped establish the impact and importance of antitrust laws. Before the implications of the Sherman Antitrust Act were clarified in early court decisions, Standard Oil had engaged in a variety of predatory tactics to weaken competitors (exclusionary conduct), purchased most of its direct rivals (horizontal integration) as well as a substantial portion of firms involved in other aspects of the oil industry (vertical integration), eventually gaining control over nearly 90 percent of U.S. oil production. Standard Oil used its size to obtain better terms on transportation and other ancillary transactions than its smaller competitors could command. These deals in turn made it easier for Standard Oil to undercut smaller rivals, softening them for purchase or forcing them out of business, reducing capacity in the industry. In 1911, the Supreme Court found for the Department of Justice, and ordered that Standard Oil Company be dissolved on the grounds that it violated the Sherman Antitrust Act’s prohibition on trusts and other business activities that restrained trade and commerce. Chapter 5 of the 2016 Economic Report of the President; available: https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/docs/ER P_2016_Chapter_5.pdf. 5 percent to almost 3,200. This would be the level associated with just three equal-sized competitors in a market.6 The FCC (2015) reports that the average HHI for wireless providers in a market increased from under 2,500 in 2004 to over 3,000 in 2014. Prater et al. (2012) document an increase in railroad market concentration between 1985 and 2007. Returns on invested capital for publicly-traded U.S. nonfinancial firms have also become increasingly concentrated within a smaller segment of the market. Figure 1 indicates that the 90th percentile firm sees returns on investments in capital that are more than five times the median. This ratio was closer to two just a quarter of a century ago. There is also evidence of a decline in the number of new firms each year. Numerous academic papers have highlighted a long-term downward trend in business dynamism—the so-called churn or birth and death rates of firms—since the 1970s (e.g., Decker et al. 2014a). Figure 2 below, which uses data from the U.S. Census consider markets in which HHI is between 1,500 and 2,500 to be moderately concentrated, and consider markets in which the HHI is in excess of 2,500 to be highly concentrated (see https://www.justice.gov/atr/herfindahl-hirschman-index for more detail). 6 The authors also report that in 2006 more than 77% of MSAs were classified as highly concentrated (i.e., having HHIs>2,500). 7 The decline in labor market dynamism was covered in greater detail in Chapter 3 of the 2015 Economic Report of the President; available: Bureau’s Business Dynamics Statistics for 1977-2013, indicates that firm entry rates have declined over time, whereas firm exit rates have been more or less steady. Moreover, recent research finds that whereas in the 1980s and 1990s, declining dynamism was observed in selected sectors, notably retail, the decline was observed across all sectors in the 2000s, including the traditionally high-growth information technology sector (Decker et al. 2014b). Labor market dynamism—which refers to the frequency of changes in who is working for whom in the labor market—has also declined since the 1970s.7 Lower rates of labor market dynamism may be due to multiple factors including lower rates of new firm entry, greater restrictions on a worker’s ability to move—such as in the case of non-compete agreements or occupational licensing described below—or even collusion between firms not to hire each other’s workers, which has occurred in Silicon Valley.8 The fact that both business and labor market dynamism have been in decline since https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/docs/20 15_erp_chapter_3.pdf . 8 Several well-known technology firms in Silicon Valley allegedly engaged in collusive “no-poaching” arrangements. More information available here: https://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/justice-department- requires-ebay-end-anticompetitive-no-poach-hiring- agreements and here: https://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/justice-department- requires-six-high-tech-companies-stop-entering- anticompetitive-employee 6 the 1970s could suggest that competition may be on the wane as well. The reasons for declining firm entry rates are not well understood, but a partial explanation is that barriers to entry may have increased in many industries. These barriers could be in the form of Federal, State, or local licenses or permits, including occupational licenses discussed below. While such regulations serve a valuable role in protecting public well-being, they can also add fixed costs to an entrepreneur wanting to open a new business. Barriers to entry may be related to various advantages that have accrued to incumbent firms over time. For example, economies of scale may mean that incumbent costs are far below those of new entrants, making it difficult for entrants to compete. Or demand- side network effects may tip the market to a single provider of the network good. But incumbent advantages could also be political in nature; for example, if existing firms successfully lobby for rules protecting them from new entrants. In summary, there is evidence of 1) increasing concentration across a number of industries, 2) increasing rents, in the form of higher returns on invested capital, across a number of firms, and 3) decreasing business and labor dynamism. However, the links among these factors are not clear. On the one hand, it could be that a decrease in firm entry is leading to higher levels of concentration, which leads to higher rents. On the other hand, it could be that higher levels of concentration are providing advantages to incumbents which are then used to raise entry barriers, leading to lower entry. Or it might be that some other factor is driving these trends. For example, innovation by a handful of firms in winner-take-all markets could give them a dominant market position in a very profitable market that could be difficult to challenge, discouraging entry. Even though it is not clear whether or how these three factors are linked, these trends are nevertheless troubling because they suggest that competition may be 9 While there are still patent litigation abuses, recent executive, judicial, and legislative actions have helped the U.S. patent litigation landscape. More details are available in an issue brief titled “The Patent Litigation Landscape: Recent Research and Developments” available here: https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/page/fil es/201603_patent_litigation_issue_brief_cea.pdf decreasing and could require attention by policymakers and regulators. Causes of Market Power There may be multiple reasons for the apparent increase in firm concentration, including deliberate behavior by firms, mergers and acquisitions activity, or State or local occupational licensing, among others. Firm Behavior Firms have for centuries engaged in behavior to expand their market. Pursuing the acquisition of market power by offering consumers greater value than rivals is a form of competition that benefits consumers, and is not itself problematic. Indeed, U.S. law recognizes the societal benefits of innovation by providing for government awards of temporary monopolies for inventions under the patent system. This potential to earn monopoly profits can provide an incentive to invest in research and development, facilitating innovations that drive technological progress. In some cases, however, the temporary monopoly afforded by a patent may not be socially productive, as may happen if a firm’s business model is to earn profits by asserting royalty rights to patents it knows to be invalid under a threat of costly patent litigation.9 However, when firms attempt to increase their profits through anticompetitive means—colluding with rivals, purchasing competitors, erecting barriers to entry to insulate their incumbency from competition, or other actions—society suffers. As a consequence, legislators, regulators and courts have directed a substantial amount of effort towards curbing such activities. In the United States, the Sherman Antitrust Act, Clayton Antitrust Act, and Federal Trade Commission Act provide front-line defenses against these abuses.10 10 The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 focused on curbing restraints on trade, including overtly anticompetitive behaviors such as price fixing. The Clayton Antitrust Act adopted an incipiency standard, designed to prevent acquisition of market power, including through anticompetitive mergers and acquisitions. 7 Mergers and Acquisitions Increased industry concentration may in part result from an uptick in merger and acquisition activity. The objective scale of takeover activity in recent years is substantial. Global activity in mergers and acquisitions surpassed $5 trillion in 2015, about $2.5 trillion of which is in the United States, the highest amount in a year on record.11 Deals surpassing $10 billion account for 37 percent of global takeover value, almost double the average of 21 percent for the last five years. However, it is important to note that the academic literature on takeover activity suggests that “merger waves” occur when stock market valuations are high, and the S&P 500 has risen almost 60 percent over the past five years during the continued recovery from the Great Recession (Maksimovic and Phillips 2001; Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan 2004). Thus, while merger activity is at an all-time high, there is some reason to believe that part of this recent trend may be due to cyclical factors rather than changes in business practices or enforcement behavior. Nevertheless, such merger activity could leave the economy with more large firms and potentially less competition. Preventing reductions in competition from mergers falls squarely within the law enforcement mission of the antitrust agencies. Proposed mergers and acquisitions that meet certain thresholds are reported to the DOJ and FTC under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976. While merger and acquisition values have spiked in recent years, the number of transactions reported to antitrust authorities has been more or less flat over the past decade, except for a notable drop in 2009 (Figure 3, left axis). In addition, during the past decade, the number of second requests issued by antitrust authorities— indicating that additional information and investigation is needed to determine whether the merger is likely to harm competition—has been relatively stable each year (Figure 3, right axis). In FY2014, 3.2 percent of mergers (51 out of 1,683 mergers) were issued a second request. The rest of the mergers were cleared within 30 days, as per 15 U.S. Code § 18(b)(1)(B). 11 These figures are according to Dealogic’s data (http://www.dealogic.com/media/market-insights/ma- statshot). From 2000 to 2007, the proportion of reported mergers with a value greater than $1 billion increased from 6 percent to close to 15 percent and then, after falling off during and just after the recession, has again begun to increase (see Figure 4, left axis). In addition, these larger transactions accounted for an increasing share of the investigations that the antitrust authorities subjected to second request (see Figure 4, right axis); in 2014, nearly half of the second requests issued were for these larger transactions.12 Occupational Licensing and Other State Laws As highlighted in a recent White House report (CEA et al. 2015), the share of workers in occupations requiring 12 However, a portion of this increase is due to the fact that transaction size is reported in nominal dollars and so naturally increases over time. 10 “pay for delay” schemes in which a brand drug manufacturer compensates another producer to delay introducing their generic version of the drug when the brand patent expires, enabling the branded product to continue to earn monopoly rents past patent expiration. DOJ challenged most-favored-nation contract clauses used by the dominant insurers in Ohio and Michigan, arguing that they raise hospital reimbursement rates to their rivals, discourage entry and innovation, and increase the price of healthcare to consumers. In 2015, the U.S. Supreme Court affirmed the FTC’s ability to challenge the North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners’s ability to block entry of unlicensed teeth whitening firms.16 The FTC argued that the Board members, primarily dentists, viewed entry by the teeth whitening firms as detrimental to their business and used their power on the State Board to block competition. (Balan et al. 2015). This case is notable given the rapid increase of licensing over the past several decades (see Figure 5 above). This decision could have pro- competitive effects going forward, as licensing boards across States adjust their behavior. Collusion Price-fixing, bid-rigging, and market-allocation agreements among firms harm competition and increase prices for consumers. The Sherman Antitrust Act prohibits “every contract, combination…., or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce,” and provides DOJ with the authority to prosecute entities and individuals who conspire to fix prices, rig bids, or allocate markets, so as to combat cartels, which the Supreme Court has deemed “the supreme evil of antitrust” (Baer 2014b). For those found guilty of these offenses, DOJ can recommend the imposition of various sanctions, including prison time and fines, as a way to hold wrongdoers accountable and punish and deter their harmful acts. For example, DOJ uncovered a conspiracy among the world’s top manufacturers of liquid crystal display (LCD) panels to fix the prices for panels used in computer monitors, notebook computers, and televisions. Their price fixing of these inputs directly affected the prices of 16 The decision can be read here: http://www.supremecourt.gov/opinions/14pdf/13- 534_19m2.pdf these consumer products. DOJ’s economic expert estimated that the conspirators’ average per-panel margin was $53 higher during the four years that they regularly met to coordinate their price fixing. The expert also testified that the conspirators’ overcharges on the panels that came into the United States were in excess of $2 billion. DOJ’s LCD panel investigation led to 13 executives being convicted and $1.3 billion in criminal fines, in addition to more than $1 billion in damages recovered by States and private plaintiffs. DOJ’s criminal prosecution of corporations and individuals and the sanctions resulting from those prosecutions have increased over time. Between 2009 and 2014, DOJ filed about 340 cases—a more than 60 percent increase over the prior five years—and charged more than 310 individuals and 110 corporations (Baer 2014a). This increased number of prosecutions has resulted in increased criminal fines. Between 2009 and 2014, DOJ obtained more than $5.4 billion in criminal fines and penalties, including a record $1.3 billion in 2014 (see Figure 6 below).17 In addition to increased fines, DOJ has sought prison sentences for more individuals, and also longer prison sentences. Since 2010, the average number of individuals sentenced to prison each year for criminal antitrust violations has increased 38 percent and the average sentence has increased from 20 months in 2000- 17 DOJ’s criminal enforcement program update is available at: http://www.justice.gov/atr/division- update/2015/criminal-program-update 11 2009 to 25 months in 2010-2014.18 The average number of defendants sentenced to jail has also increased, from 21 in the 2000s to 29 in 2010-2014 (see Figure 7 below).19 Over time, these enhanced criminal enforcement activities could have a deterrent effect. Antitrust law also prohibits agreements to fix wages or limit competition for workers. For example, DOJ has successfully challenged—through civil enforcement— agreements that limited competition for nurses in both Arizona and Utah. Registered nurses (RN) in a number of areas of the country have filed private antitrust suits alleging that hospitals colluded with their local competitors to avoid recruiting each other’s workers, thus depressing wages (Blair and DePasquale 2010). Agency and Sector Specific Actions Many other government agencies also have the ability to engage in sector-specific regulation and rule-making to affect pro-competitive outcomes. There have been multiple examples of such actions over the past several years, often in collaboration with competition advocacy efforts by the antitrust agencies. • Airport Access. The DOT has in some proceedings successfully sought divestitures of airlines’ “slots”— the right to fly in and out of a capacity-constrained airport at a given time—to allow new competitors 18Assistant Attorney General Bill Baer’s Testimony before the Oversight of the Antitrust Enforcement Agencies – House Judiciary Committee, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law, May access to this critical resource. These actions can facilitate entry by new competitors. For example, the FAA recently changed the designation of Newark Liberty International Airport from a “slot-controlled” to a “schedule-facilitated” airport. With this change in designation, any airline currently holding slots at the airport will need to use them or relinquish them to other airlines. The FAA’s action therefore potentially gives more airlines access to the airport, potentially increasing competition between airlines, which could ultimately lead to lower prices and/or higher quality services for travelers. • Net Neutrality. The FCC’s 2010 Open Internet order, and its subsequent 2015 action, were aimed at ensuring that broadband providers do not exploit their “terminating access monopoly” over consumers to privilege their own vertically integrated content or discriminate against others’ content or force content providers to pay fees for access or preferential access to customers. In other words, broadband providers who have a monopoly over service to their individual customers may not provide faster or better access to their own content versus content provided by others. This action represents regulatory intervention targeting not just potential for anticompetitive behavior in the consumer market for Internet service providers, but potential competitive harms for other markets (video content, social media platforms, etc.) that depended on potential access to all online consumers regardless of their Internet service providers. • Wireless Spectrum. The FCC has taken a number of steps to promote competition through ensuring competitive access to radiofrequency spectrum, a limited resource that allows telecommunications equipment like cellular phones and televisions to function. In its most recent design of a spectrum auction, the FCC established a market-based spectrum reserve designed to ensure against excessive concentration in holdings of low-band spectrum, and updated its bidding credit rules to 15, 2015, http://www.justice.gov/atr/congressional- testimony. 19 Also available from the criminal program update: http://www.justice.gov/atr/division- update/2015/criminal-program-update 12 provide meaningful opportunities to bona fide small businesses and rural service providers to participate in auctions. In 2015, the FCC also updated its spectrum screen used for competitive reviews of proposed secondary market transactions. • Cell Phone Unlocking. Historically, when a consumer purchased a cellphone and signed a contract with a telecommunications service provider, he or she was often unable to switch networks (and thus service providers) while still using the same device. Because of certain software that resided on the device, this constraint was present even when the new network and the device were technologically compatible. The device could thus be said to be “locked” to this original network. In light of the fact that cell phone locking impedes consumer choice in the marketplace, the FCC worked to secure voluntary commitments from the wireless industry so that new policies could be adopted to reduce the scope, incidence, and impact of this practice. As of February 2015, all nationwide mobile service providers adopted six standards that had been laid out in 2014 by CTIA-The Wireless Association, an industry group.20 • Defense Acquisition and Procurement. As part of its Better Buying Power initiative, begun in 2010 and now in its third iteration, the Department of Defense (DoD) has focused more intensively on promoting competition among contractors that provide the military with goods and services. This initiative was undertaken in recognition of the fact that competition not only reduces prices and increases the quality and variety of goods and services but also spurs innovation and affords small businesses the opportunity to enter new markets, potentially boosting overall productivity of the defense industrial base. Importantly, because innovations in defense technologies often also have civilian applications, this form of innovation has the potential to impact the overall economy positively as well. • Standard-Essential Patents (SEPs). Voluntary consensus standards set by standards-developing 20 FCC provides a list of frequently asked questions about cell phone unlocking on its website as well as the list of the exact standards laid out by CTIA and subsequently organizations (SDOs) have paved the way for innovation that allows consumers to use the many innovative features of today’s smart phones and computers, from e-mailing and texting to making video calls and watching videos. Often participants in a standard-setting process will voluntarily commit to license their patents that are essential to such standards, called SEPs, on fair, reasonable, and non- discriminatory (F/RAND) terms, in exchange for the benefit of being included in the standard. The International Trade Commission (ITC) was asked to issue an exclusion order in Samsung’s case against Apple for infringing its SEPs. During the ITC’s investigation, DOJ and the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) released a Joint Statement that outlined circumstances where the issuance of an exclusion order might fail to satisfy the ITC’s public interest standard. It said that a credible threat of an exclusion order, which would ban an alleged infringer’s competitive products from the market, could allow SEP owners to renege on their F/RAND commitment and extract supra-competitive royalty payments. This, in turn, could harm consumers through higher prices and stifle innovation by increasing the risks for companies seeking to implement standardized technology. In reviewing the ITC’s exclusion order, the U.S. Trade Representative (USTR) shared the concerns of the Joint Statement and disapproved the order issued by the ITC against Apple and in favor of Samsung. At the same time, the executive agencies all strongly supported the protection of intellectual property rights and the ability of SEP holders who make F/RAND commitments to receive appropriate compensation. The Joint Statement and USTR’s disapproval demonstrate how agencies of the executive branch can work together to promote and protect competition and consumers while protecting intellectual property rights. Potential Areas for Future Consideration Looking forward, as more and more sectors of the economy are digitized, departments and agencies may need to consider how digitization is impacting competition and whether additional regulation is adopted by all nationwide wireless service providers: https://www.fcc.gov/consumers/guides/cell-phone- unlocking-faqs 15 Baer, Bill. 2014a. “Reflections on Antitrust Enforcement in the Obama Administration. Remarks as Prepared for the New York State Bar Association.” January 30. https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/517761/download Baer, Bill. 2014b. “Prosecuting Antitrust Crimes. Remarks as Prepared for the Georgetown University Law Center Global Antitrust Enforcement Symposium.” September 10. https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/517741/download Balan, David J., Patrick DeGraba, Francine Lafontaine, Patrick McAlvanah, Devesh Raval, and David Schmidt. 2015. “Economics at the FTC: Fraud, Mergers and Exclusion.” Review of Industrial Organization 47(4): 371- 398. Blair, Roger D. and Christina DePasquale, 2010. “Monopsony and Countervailing Power in the Market for Nurses.” Antitrust Health Care Chronicle, December. http://economics.emory.edu/home/documents/docum ents/Depasqualechristina_1.pdf Boal, William M. 1995. “Testing for Employer Monopsony in Turn-of-the-century Coal Mining.” The RAND Journal of Economics 26(3): 519-536. Brandenburger, Adam M. and Harborne W. Stuart, Jr. 1996. “Value-based Business Strategy.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 5(1), 5-24. Brown, Jeffrey R. and Austan Goolsbee. 2002. “Does the Internet Make Markets More Competitive? Evidence from the Life Insurance Industry.” June, Journal of Political Economy 110(3): 481-507. Brynjolfsson, Erik and Michael D. Smith. 2000. “Frictionless Commerce? A Comparison of Internet and Conventional Retailers.” Management Science 46(4): 563-585. Cabral, Luis M.B. 2000. Introduction to Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT press. Corbae, Dean and Pablo D’Erasmo. 2013. “A Quantitative Model of Banking Industry Dynamics.” Council of Economic Advisers (CEA), Department of Labor, and the Department of the Treasury. 2015. “Occupational Licensing: A Framework for Policymakers.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/docs/li censing_report_final_nonembargo.pdf Council of Economic Advisers. 2015. Economic Report of the President. February. Council of Economic Advisers. 2016. Economic Report of the President. February. Crawford, Gregory and Ali Yurukoglu. 2012. “The Welfare Effects of Bundling in Multichannel Television Markets.” The American Economic Review 102(2): 643-685. Dafny, Leemore. 2005. “Games Hospitals Play: Entry Deterrence in Hospital Procedure Markets.” Journal of Economic and Management Strategy 14: 513-542. Decker, Ryan, John Haltiwanger, Ron Jarmin, and Javier Miranda. 2014a. “The Role of Entrepreneurship in US Job Creation and Economic Dynamism”. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (3): 3–24. Decker, Ryan, John Haltiwanger, Ron S Jarmin, and Javier Miranda. 2014b. “The Secular Decline in Business Dynamism in the U.S.” University of Maryland working paper. Dixit, Avinash. 1980. “The Role of Investment in Entry- Deterrence.” The Economic Journal 90(357): 95-106. Education Superhighway. 2015. “2015 State of the States. A report on the state of broadband connectivity in America’s public schools.” November. http://cdn.educationsuperhighway.org/assets/sos/full_ report-c2e60c6937930e8ca5cdbf49d45d45c8.pdf Farrell, Joseph, Janis K. Pappalardo, and Howard Shelanski. 2010. “Economics at the FTC: Mergers, dominant-firm conduct, and consumer behavior.” Review of Industrial Organization 37(4): 263-277. Federal Communications Commission. 2015. “Eighteenth Mobile Wireless Competition Report.” https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DA-15- 1487A1.pdf Fuglie, Keith, Paul Heisey, John King, and David Schimmelpfennig. 2012. “Rising Concentration in Agricultural Input Industries Influences New Farm Technologies.” U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). 16 http://www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2012- december/rising-concentration-in-agricultural-input- industries-influences-new-technologies.aspx#.Vw- e2fkrLRY Furman, Jason, and Peter Orszag. 2015. “A Firm-Level Perspective on the Role of Rents in the Rise in Inequality.” Paper presented at Columbia University’s “A Just Society” Centennial Event in Honor of Joseph Stiglitz, New York, NY. Gaynor, Martin, Kate Ho, and Robert J. Town. 2015. “The Industrial Organization of Health-Care Markets.” Journal of Economic Literature 53(2): 235-84. Goolsbee, Austan, and Chad Syverson. 2008. “How Do Incumbents Respond to the Threat of Entry? Evidence from the Major Airlines.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123: 1611-1633. Gowrisankaran, Gautam, Aviv Nevo, and Robert Town. 2015. “Mergers When Prices are Negotiated.” American Economic Review 105 (1): 172-203. Hicks, J.R. 1935. “Annual Survey of Economic Theory: The Theory of Monopoly.” Econometrica 3(1): 1-20. Hotelling, Harold. 1929. “Stability in Competition.” The Economic Journal 39(153): 41-57. Kleiner, Morris M. and Alan B. Krueger. 2013. “Analyzing the Extent and Influence of Occupational Licensing on the Labor Market.” Journal of Labor Economics 31 (2): S173-S202. Kovacic, William E. and Carl Shapiro. 2000. “Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(1): 43-60. Koller, Tim et al. 2015. Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies. Sixth Edition. John Wiley & Sons. Kwoka Jr, John E. 2013. “Does Merger Control Work? A Retrospective on US Enforcement Actions and Merger Outcomes.” Antitrust Law Journal 78 (3): 619-650. Kwoka, Jr. John E. and Diana L. Moss. 2012. “Behavioral Merger Remedies: Evaluation and Implications for Antitrust Enforcement.” The Antitrust Bulletin 57(4): 979-1011. Kyle, Margaret K., and David B. Ridley. 2007. “Would Greater Transparency and Uniformity of Health Care Prices Benefit Poor Patients?” Health Affairs 26 (5): 1384- 1391. Maksimovic, Vojislav and Gordon Phillips. 2001. “The Market for Corporate Assets: Who Engages in Mergers and Asset Sales and Are There Efficiency Gains?” Journal of Finance 56(6): 2019-2065. Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts. 1982. “Limit Pricing and Entry Under Incomplete Information: An Equilibrium Analysis.” Econometrica 50(2): 443-459. O'Brien, Daniel P. and Steven C. Salop. 2000. “Competitive Effects of Partial Pwnership: Financial Interest and Corporate Control.” Antitrust Law Journal 67(3): 559-614. Prater, Marvin E., Ken Casavant, Eric Jessup, Bruce Blanton, Pierre Bahizi, Daniel Nibarger, and Isaac Weingram. 2012. “Rail Competition Changes Since the Staggers Act.” Journal of the Transportation Research Forum 49(3): 111-132. Rhodes-Kropf, Matthew and Viswanathan, S. 2004. “Market Valuation and Merger Waves.” The Journal of Finance 59(6): 2685-2718. Rotemberg, Julio J. and Garth Saloner. 1986. “A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Price Wars During Booms.” The American Economic Review 76(3): 390-407. Schultz, Christian. 2005. “Transparency on the Consumer Side and Tacit Collusion.” European Economic Review 49 (2): 279-297. Seamans, Robert C. 2012. “Fighting City Hall: Entry Deterrence and Technology Upgrades in Cable TV Markets.” Management Science 58(3): 461–475. Shapiro, Carl. 2012. “Competition and Innovation: Did Arrow Hit the Bull’s Eye?” in The Rate & Direction of Economic Activity Revisited, Josh Lerner and Scott Stern, eds. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 17 Shields, Dennis A. 2010. “Consolidation and Concentration in the U.S. Dairy Industry.” April 27. Congressional Research Service. http://nationalaglawcenter.org/wp- content/uploads/assets/crs/R41224.pdf Shub, Gary, Brent Beardsley, Helene Donnadieu, Nick Gardiner, Craig Hapelt, Benoît Macé, Neil Pardasani, Katie Tamarelli, Tjun Tang, and Yasuhiro Yamai. 2015. “Global Asset Management 2015: Sparking Growth with Go-to-Market Excellence.” BCG Perspectives. https://www.bcgperspectives.com/content/articles/fina ncial-institutions-global-asset-management-2015- sparking-growth-through-go-to-market-strategy/ Shughart, William F. and Diana W. Thomas. 2013. “Antitrust Enforcement in the Obama Administration’s First Term. A Regulatory Approach.” Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 739. Spence, A. Michael. 1977. “Entry, Capacity, Investment and Oligopolistic Pricing.” The Bell Journal of Economics 8(2): 534-544. Stigler, George. 1964. “A Theory of Oligopoly.” Journal of Political Economy 72 (1): 44–61. Tenn, Steven and Brett W. Wendling. 2014. “Entry Threats and Pricing in the Generic Drug Industry.” Review of Economics and Statistics 96(2): 214–228 Tirole, Jean. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Zettelmeyer, Florian, Fiona Scott Morton, and Jorge Silva-Russo. 2001. “Cowboys or Cowards: Why are Internet Car Prices Lower?” NBER Working Paper 8667.
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved