Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

The Impact of Free City-States in the Middle Ages on Civic Capital in Italian Cities, Lecture notes of Economics

City-StatesCivic CapitalSelf-GovernmentMedieval HistoryItalian History

A study that examines the correlation between Italian cities that experienced self-government in the Middle Ages and their current level of civic capital. The research compares different measures of civic capital in cities that were once free city-states and finds that they exhibit higher levels of civic capital, even after controlling for income levels and inequality. The study also investigates the factors that facilitated the creation of free city-states and their relationship with civic capital in the Center-North and the South of Italy.

What you will learn

  • How does the study control for potential confounding variables?
  • What factors facilitated the creation of free city-states in Italy?
  • How does the study measure civic capital in Italian cities?

Typology: Lecture notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 09/12/2022

jamal33
jamal33 🇺🇸

4.3

(47)

107 documents

1 / 33

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download The Impact of Free City-States in the Middle Ages on Civic Capital in Italian Cities and more Lecture notes Economics in PDF only on Docsity! 1 This Version: June 2014 Long-term Persistence1 Luigi Guiso Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance & CEPR Paola Sapienza Northwestern University, NBER, & CEPR Luigi Zingales University of Chicago, NBER, & CEPR Abstract We study whether historical shocks can generate long term persistence in development by fostering a better culture. We show that Italian cities that experienced self-government in the Middle Ages have higher level of civic capital today than similar cities that did not. Not only the occurrence of a free city state, but also the length of this experience and its intensity seems to impact civic capital positively. JEL: O43, P16, O10 Keywords: social capital, culture, persistence, institutions 1 A previous version of the paper circulated under the title “Was Putnam Right?” We thank Francesco Giavazzi, Paola Giuliano, Eliana La Ferrara, Giuliano Milani, Guido Tabellini, and participants in seminars at Brown University, the University of Chicago, New York University, European University Institute, Stockholm University and the NBER for very helpful comments. We are most grateful to Giuliano Milani for his advice and help in obtaining data and references on medieval history and Andrea Pellizzari for help in identifying Roman colonies. We thank the Invalsi Institute for providing us with city-level data on cheating in school. Lorenzo Ciari, Marcello Sartarelli, and Luca Riva have provided excellent research assistance and Peggy Eppink and Janice Luce invaluable editorial help. Luigi Guiso thanks the European University Institute, Paola Sapienza the Zell Center, and Luigi Zingales the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP), the Stigler Center, and the Initiative on Global Markets at the University of Chicago for financial support. 2 Although history holds examples of spectacular catch-ups, relative national levels of economic development tend to be quite persistent over time. The per capita income of European countries at the end of the twentieth century had a 0.56 correlation with their per capita income at the beginning of the century. Even over the 300-year span from the eighteenth to the twenty-first century the correlation is 0.23. 2 This correlation persists despite the massive destruction of physical and human capital in Europe’s recurrent warfare. Why are these differences in economic development so persistent? In an influential paper, Acemoglu et al. (2001) attribute the phenomenon to the long- lasting effect of formal institutions, such as protection of property rights and limitations on the power of the executive. Ingrained into a country’s legal rules, these institutions tend to endure over the centuries. Consistent with this view, they find that countries inhospitable to white men still suffer of low property rights protection and excessive executive power because the European colonizers, who did not intend to stay, designed legal institutions aimed at extracting rather than creating value. This influential explanation faces three objections. First, how can we differentiate the role of legal institutions from that of the culture and the human capital that the colonizers brought to the colonies (Glaeser et al. 2004)? Second, if persistence depends on legal institutions, why should these be so persistent themselves? After all, they are designed to be changeable. Even constitutions, the least flexible of legal institutions, are often changed: Argentina, which has had four different constitutions in the last 60 years, is a case in point. Finally, can we completely reject the hypothesis that persistence depends on geographical factors?3 An alternative interpretation, going back to Putnam et al. (1993), attributes the persistence of economic development to culture. Williamson (2000) claims that culture is the most persistent of all institutions and, unlike legal institutions, has no explicit mechanisms for amendment. Yet even Williamson (2000) is not clear why and when culture is so persistent. Putnam (2000) himself documents an example of the rapid deterioration of social capital in America. Does culture persist only when it is optimal, or does it tend to outlive its usefulness and the environment that generated it? To address these questions we revisit Putnam’s hypothesis. He conjectures that civic capital differences across Italian regions are due to a different incidence of free city states 2 These results are obtained using Maddison (2001). 3 Acemoglu et al. (2001) discuss this challenge and argue that the diseases that were once a serious problem (yellow fever and malaria) no longer represent a major source of comparative disadvantage today. Still, other geographical factors impeding economic development could be at the origin of this persistence. 5 technology’s disappearance. Grosjean (2011), for instance, studies a culture of violence functional to a pastoral society; Alesina et al. (2013) examine the diffusion of the plow in agriculture (which gave a comparative advantage to men over women). We provide novel evidence for this long-term persistence highlighting the interplay between an important historical episode, the new formal institutions it gives rise to, and the culture these institutions created, which outlived the institutions themselves for centuries. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 1 provides a brief primer on Italian medieval history, illustrating the logical connection between the conquest of political independence and the development of civic capital. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 analyses of the effect of the free city-state experience within the Center- North. Section 4 concludes. 1. A primer in Italian medieval history 1.1 Civic capital and the free city-state experience The term “social capital” has been used to indicate several often quite divergent concepts. Following Putnam et al. (1993) and Fukuyama (1995), we focus on “civic capital” and define it as “those persistent and shared beliefs and values that help a group overcome the free rider problem in the pursuit of socially valuable activities” (Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales, 2011). The question is how these values and beliefs arise and how they are transmitted over time. The Italian free city-state experience offers an interesting natural experiment. As we explain below, a number of historical conditions (the presence of a religious authority, strategic location, and distance from the imperial army’s headquarters) determined some towns to achieve successful cooperation in defending themselves, while others did not. And since these historical conditions and the corresponding resulting formal institutions are long gone, this setting allows us to study whether an experience of cooperation may leave a legacy of values and beliefs that survive the circumstances that originally determined them. 1.2 The rise of the free city-states At the end of the first millennium the Center-North Italian regions were part of the Holy Roman Empire, which was on the way to disintegration. Between 1061 and 1091 the Normans invaded the Southern part of Italy and formed a strong state, which guaranteed order and stability. 6 By contrast, in the Center-North the vacuum created by the demise of the imperial authority led to the emergence of a number of independent city-states.6 The first nucleus in the emergence of these city-states was the establishment of a “sworn pact” (patto giurato) in which a town’s inhabitants agreed to provide mutual help and collaborate to solve problems of common interest (Prodi, 1992). In some cases these pacts were enforced by the threat of exclusion from trade (Milani, 2005), a very costly punishment at a time when trade opportunities were very profitable. In others (e.g. Pisa), a third party – the city bishop – was assigned to act as guarantor. His presence added an enforcement mechanism otherwise not available: the threat of exclusion from religious communion (Tabacco, 1987), facilitating coordination. The pre-eminent common interest was defense against the Emperor’s claim to exert power over the city. This battle culminated in 1176 when a league of free cities (communes) in the North of Italy, the Lombard League, defeated Emperor Fredrick I in the Battle of Legnano. Unlike the Norman kingdom, located in South of Italy, the communes made their rules, laws, and formal decisions in the name of the people, because political power was said to derive from the people, not from some religious authority or divine right. While the medieval communes should not be equated with modern democracies, they did introduce many aspects of the system that today goes under the name of “rule of law.” For example, government officials’ actions were subjected to the control of new institutions, including courts of law to which citizens could appeal (Galizia, 1951). 1.3. From the Commune to the Signoria: evolution and dissolution of the Italian city-states In the course of the fifteenth century, Italian communes began to confer life-long power on a single person – the Lord or Signore, hence the name Signoria. In several cases the Signoria retained the fundamental institutions of the commune, including the principle that power originated from the people and was to be exercised in the people’s name. In cities such as Florence and Genoa, the Signoria also preserved the political institutions and the personal liberties that had characterized the commune period. In this sense the Signoria was a continuation and transformation of the commune (as is maintained by Prezzolini, 1948 and Chittolini, 1999), which might have allowed the civic culture to become deeply rooted, especially by comparison with the cities that were conquered and subjugated by other towns or foreign powers. 6 Within the Center North the only region in which free cities did not develop is Lazio where the Papal influence prevented independence. 7 If, as conjectured by Putnam, the regional differences in civic capital are due to the free city state experience, then civic capital today should be higher in cities that were free cities in the Middle Ages. Furthermore, this difference should be more pronounced the longer the independence of the city lasted. 2. The Data In this section we describe how we collected the data. A synthetic description of each variable is contained in Table 1, while the Online Appendix contains a more detailed description of the sources and methodologies used. In total, our sample contains 5,372 cities located in the Center North. For a small part of the analysis we will compare the Center-North and the South. Our sample of southern cities contains 2,175 observations. 2.1 Identifying the communes As observed above, free cities could emerge only in the parts of Italy that were under the Empire at the beginning of the second millennium (see Figure A1 in the Online Appendix). We focus on this area, which comprises twelve of Italy’s present-day regions.7 Historians appear to agree that a commune, properly so called, needs to meet four criteria: it should have consuls as part of its institutions; it should have its own institutions to administer justice; it should have some military power and military activity; and finally, it should have its own rural territory (the contado) to administer (Milani, 2005). As far as we know, there is no comprehensive history of Italian communes. Thus, verifying these conditions in all the Italian cities existing today during three centuries is extremely difficult. We chose instead to start from the sample of free cities identified by a prominent historical atlas (De Agostini, 2007). To validate this source we also consulted several additional historical sources (see Online Appendix) to verify that the towns identified as communes by the Atlas met the four historical criteria. None of the city states in the map have been eliminated. This procedure may underestimate the number of free cities, biasing against finding any effect. Using several historical sources we also constructed a measure of duration of independence and an indicator for whether or not a Commune evolved into a Signoria (see the Online Appendix for more details). 7Piedmont, Valle D’Aosta, Liguria, Lombardy, Trentino, Veneto, Friuli-Venezia Giulia, Emilia-Romagna, Tuscany, Umbria, Marche, and Lazio. Since Sardinia was neither part of the Holy Roman Empire, nor under Norman domination, we have excluded it from the sample altogether. We also excluded Rome, given its truly unique history, as an exceptional case. 10 Other important historical characteristics are whether a town was a colony of ancient Rome and whether it was located at a Roman crossroad. We identified former Roman colonies from Brill’s New Pauly (2003). Roman roads are identified from the Touring Club Historical Atlas of Italy and the “Reference Map of Ancient Italy”. We then map ancient cities into today location by using Google Maps. We use the Treccani (2007) to identify the cities with a bishop seat and the cities where Emperor Henry IV passed through when in 1083 he came down to Italy to assert his imperial power. These cities became strongholds of his army. We use the same source to identify the presence of a marquis. At the time of Charlemagne the Center-North of Italy was divided into marches, so the survival of strong marches represents the persistence of imperial power. Finally, all the other variables (including the average elevation, other geographic controls, population, per capita income and per capita wealth) are from Ancitel (2014), a database assembled by the association of municipal administrations, which reports over 320 variables at municipal level for the period 2003-04. Table 2 shows summary statistics for all our variables. 3. Empirical analysis 3.1 Basic specification Our first measure of civic capital is the number of non-profit organizations divided by the 2001 population (Table 3, Panel A). In column 1, we regress this measure on a simple indicator of whether a town was a free city in 1176 and several geographical controls. To control for mountain location we insert the average elevation. To control for geographically-driven differences in the cost of interaction, we insert the maximum elevation difference within the municipality’s territory. We also control for coastal location (i.e. within five kilometers of the sea). Finally, as a measure of size, we control for the number of inhabitants (thousands of people) in 2001. Since we are unsure how population affects civic capital, we insert both population and population squared. Since the measures of civic capital tend to be noisier for smaller towns, we use the weighted least squared method, weighted by the population in 2001. The impact of the free city-state experience is large and statistically significant at the 1% level. Towns that were communes have two more associations per thousand inhabitants (30% more than the average). Though this estimate is obtained using only variation within the Center- North, its magnitude is half of the difference in civic capital between Center-North and South. Another known determinant of civic capital (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2002) is income inequality. For this reason, column 2 adds two Gini measures of inequality: in land ownership 11 and in pre-tax income. These additions run the risk of overcontrolling, since inequality could be an effect rather than a cause of persistently low civic capital. Surprisingly, greater income inequality leads to more civic capital, as measured by the number of non-profit associations per capita, but this effect is due to the lack of a control for per capita income. When we introduce this control (column 5) the effect vanishes. Regardless, the impact of once having been a commune remains unchanged. While we control for population and population squared, it is still possible that our estimated effect may only reflect some non-linearity between city size and civic capital. For this reason, in column 3 we exclude from the sample the largest towns (more than 120,000 inhabitants in 2001). The effect of the free city-state experience remains unchanged. Two thirds of the medieval city-states are provincial capitals today. This administrative role could confer a different status on the city, possibly affecting the level of civic capital. For example, associations might find it convenient to be located near the local administration. For this reason, in column 4 we exclude from the sample all provincial capitals from the regression. The effect of the commune experience is undiminished. Glaeser et al. (2002) show that individual investment in social interaction increases with per capita income. Since towns that became independent in the Middle Ages were likely to be richer, the free city-state experience might be a proxy for unobserved characteristics that make for prosperity.11 To address this issue we would like to be able to factor in per capita income in 1100 CE. Unfortunately, no such measure is available, so we have to resort to today’s per capita income. This specification will clearly underestimate the impact of the free city-state experience because, as Knack and Keefer (1997) show, civic capital itself fosters growth, so that the greater civic capital generated by the city-state experience translates into higher per capita income. As column 5 shows, wealthier towns do in fact display a higher level of civic capital, so, as expected, the insertion of this variable reduces the impact of the free city-state experience on today’s level of civic capital. The effect of the communal experience, however, remains positive and economically and statistically significant. In addition, in an unreported regression we control also for a city level measure of human capital: the average math score of the pupils. Since Italy has a national curriculum, this score reflects the average quality of local schools and teachers and thus the average level of human capital in the area. This control does not have any effect on our first two measures of civic capital. It does have an effect on the third, reducing the coefficient and 11 Of course the fact that some very wealthy towns in the South, such as Salerno and Palermo, even richer than Center-Northern towns, did not become free cities suggests that what was driving independence was not linked to unobserved economic prosperity. 12 reducing the statistical significance just above the 10% level (p=10.6). Yet, this is hardly surprising, since in places where scores are naturally high it is more difficult to detect cheating Finally, in column 6 we add four area dummies to capture possible unobserved heterogeneity in civic capital across regions in our sample (Northeast, Northwest, Center-North, and Center) due to other historical factors. These dummies (not reported) are all statistically significant, but inserting them does not change the impact of the free city-state experience on civic capital. In the first three columns of Table 3, Panel B, we repeat the estimation using our second measure of civic capital, the presence of an organ donation association. Again the effect of the city-state experience is positive and statistically significant in all the specifications. Having been an independent city-state increases the probability of having an organ donation association by 41%. In the last three columns of Table 3B, we estimate the same specification by using our measure of cheating as left hand side variable. Here the effect is negative and statistically significant in all specifications. Having been a free city-state decreases our standardized measure of cheating by 13% of the mean.12 The concentration of free city-states among the larger cities suggests the possibility that our sample is too heterogeneous and that even controlling for size and size squared, the coefficient of our explanatory variable might be a spurious effect. Accordingly, we select the 400 largest cities. To minimize possible survivorship bias we select them according to the earliest Census data available (immediately after national unification in 1861). Table 4, Panel A, shows the results using this smaller sample. The first three columns of Table 4A show the results using the controls in the specification in the second column of Table 3 (the other specifications are reported in the Online Appendix – Table A1, Panel A). The effect is roughly halved when the sample is restricted to these cities, but it still remains both quantitatively meaningful and statistically significant. The advantage of this reduced sample is the availability of more sophisticated controls for the towns’ history: a dummy for being located at an ancient Roman crossroads, one for being along the itinerary of Emperor Henry IV, one for having been a Roman colony, one for having belonged to a marquis and, finally, two dummies for medium and large size in 1300. When we introduce these controls, the effect of the free city-state variable on all three measures of civic capital is unchanged. 12 The estimated coefficient is significant also in all the other specifications reported in Table 3A except that in which we drop the largest towns. While this sample eliminates only 19 observations, 17 represent former city-states, reducing the sample of these by 26%. 15 third for Imperial allies. When using organ donations as LHS variable the pattern is similar (column 2). In fact, the effect of cities that were part of the Lombard League is 28% larger than that of neutral city-states and almost twice as large as that of the Emperor’s allied states. However, when we measure civic capital with cheating (column 3) the largest effect is produced by the neutral cities. So far, our results indicate that free city states were a transforming experience for some areas of the Center-North and that those areas today are characterized by high civic capital. Because the free city states are long gone and these cities now have the same formal institutions, these correlations lend support to Putnam’s conjecture that the setup of those cities fostered a new culture that has persisted until today and it is captured by our measures of civic capital. 3.3 The origin of free city states Our geographical controls mitigate the concern that we are capturing a spurious correlation between the free city experience and civic capital. Yet, it is still possible that the free city state experience, since it is not random, is correlated with some characteristics (other than cultural) that persists to this day and sustain a greater level of civic capital. To address this concern we resort to the historians’ analysis of the origins of free city states. Since the strong central power exerted by the Norman Kingdom in the South did not allow the formation of free cities, we can design a counterfactual. If the free city state experience is the result of a spurious correlation driven by some characteristics of free city states, then these characteristics should have the same correlation with civic capital in the South, where free city states could not emerge. Vice versa, if it is the specific free city state experience to drive the correlation, then these factors should not be correlated with civic capital in the South, where this experience did not (and could not) occur. One of the obstacles to the formation of a free city is the cost of coordination. Historians (Reynolds (1997), Milani (2005), Jones (1997), Tabacco (1987), and Pirenne (1956)) suggest that bishops reduced this cost, providing moral sanctioning to the citizens’ agreements. According to this view, the existence of a bishop seat in the city in year 1000 is a good proxy for the ease of coordination and is correlated with the creation of communes in Italy. In unreported regressions, we find indeed that this variable is highly predictive of the probability that a town became a free city state. The first three columns of Table 6, Panel A, present the correlation between this historical determinant of free city states and civic capital. The results show that the presence of a bishop has a positive and significant correlation with the level of civic capital, measured by our 16 three proxies, in the North. To verify that this effect is not capturing some alternative reason for higher civic capital in free city states, we investigate the correlation between the presence of a bishop in the South and the level of civic capital. In the last three columns of Table 6 Panel A, we estimate the same specification in the South. Differently than in the North sample, the presence of a bishop has an insignificant correlation with the presence of non-profit organizations and with frequency of children’s cheating on a national math tests. In other words, when the presence of a bishop cannot foster the formation of free city states, the presence of a diocese is not associated with higher levels of civic capital, as measured by these two proxies, suggesting the correlations observed in Tables 2 to 4 are not spurious. Instead, the presence of a bishop in the South has a positive relation, albeit smaller than in the North sample, with the presence of an organ donor association. In order to provide one further validity check against the presence of spurious correlations, we study the correlation between dioceses created after the period in which the free city state experience took place (i.e., towns that were assigned a bishop seat after 1400) and civic capital. Sixty-three cities in the Center-North became dioceses after 1400. As Table 6, Panel B shows, the assignment of a bishop seat after 1400 has a negative and significant correlation with civic capital, measured by the presence of non-profit organization. This result rules out that the presence of a bishop, in itself, is conducive to greater civic capital. Columns two and three of Table 6B show that there is no correlation with dioceses formed after 1400 and the presence of organ donor associations and the frequency of cheating in math tests. This evidence suggests that, while the free city state is not a random occurrence, the initial characteristics that facilitated independence are linked to higher civic capital only through the transformative city state experience. In other regions in Italy, where the same initial conditions existed but could not deliver free city states, or in subsequent periods where the initial conditions could not spur independence, we do not find a positive correlation with civic capital. 4. Conclusion Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) claim that shocks to institutions can affect outcomes over prolonged periods of time. Yet, they do not distinguish whether this impact is the direct effect of formal institutions’ persistence or the indirect effect produced by institutional shocks on people’s psyche and culture. In other terms is culture or are formal institutions the source of long term persistence? In this paper we try to disentangle the two by looking at an institutional change whose formal institutions have long gone: Italian free-city states. We examine the different levels of 17 civic capital today between the towns that during the Middle Ages were free city-states and those that were not. Not only the establishment but also the duration and degree of independence of the historical free city states affect today’s civic capital positively. Our evidence highlights the existence of cultural persistence where attitudes developed during an important historical event are passed from generation to generation. These attitudes may be transmitted from parents to children, as in Bisin and Verdier (2000, 2001) (see also Tabellini (2008) and Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2008b) for other models of intergenerational transmission). This mechanism is particularly credible in Italy, where many centuries-old customs and traditions still survive today. This paper does not identify the mechanism through which this very long-term persistence takes place. One possibility (Putnam, 2000 and Ostrom, 1990) is that direct participation to public life (like in the commune) trains people to cooperate and somehow this attitude is transmitted through generations even when this participations cannot take place anymore. Another, advanced by Tabellini (2008) and Rothstein (2011), is that transparent and democratic institutions affect citizens’ beliefs about trustworthiness and fairness (and similarly these beliefs are transmitted through generations). A third hypothesis is that historical events affect a nation’s psyche, changing the attitudes of its citizens through a socialization process very clearly identified by Banfield (1958). We will try to distinguish among these hypotheses in future work. 20 Jones, Philip, “The Italian City-state. From Commune to Signoria”, Clarendon Press, Oxford University Press, Oxford (1997). Knack, S. and P. Keefer, “Does social capital have an economic pay-off? A cross country investigation”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 4 (1997), pp: 1251-1288. Maddison, Angus, (2001), “The World Economy: A Millennial perspective”, OCED. Milani, Giuliano, I Comuni Italiani, Editori Laterza, Bari (2005). Ministero del Lavoro, Registri delle Associazioni Provinciali, Roma (2005). Nunn, Nathan, and Leonard Wantchekon, “The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in Africa,” American Economic Review, Vol. 101, No 7 (2011), pp: 3221–3252. Ostrom, Elinor, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1990) Pirenne, Henri, The Medieval City, Princeton University Press, Princeton (1956). Prezzolini, Giuseppe, The Legacy of Italy, Vanni, New York (1948). Prodi, Paolo, Il sacramento del potere. Il giuramento politico nella storia costituzionale dell'Occidente, Il Mulino, Bologna (1992). Putnam, Robert, Robert Leonardi and Raffaella Nanetti, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Simon & Schuster, New York (1993). Putnam, Robert, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community, Simon & Schuster, New York (2000). Reynolds, Susan, Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe 900-1300, second edition, Clarendon Press, Oxford University Press, Oxford (1997). Rothstein, Bo, The Quality of Government. Corruption, Social Trust, and Inequality in International Perspective, University of Chicago Press, Chicago (2011). Tabacco, Giovanni, “La città vescovile nell'alto Medioevo”, in Modelli di città. Strutture e funzioni politiche, edited by P. Rossi, Edizioni Comunità, Torino (1987). Tabellini, Guido, “The scope of cooperation: norms and incentives,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 123, No. 3(2008), pp. 905-950. Tabellini, Guido, “Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 8, No. 4(2010), pp: 1542-4774. Touring Club Italiano, Guide Rosse d’Italia, Regioni Italiane, (2000), Milano. Touring Club Italiano, Atlante Storico del Touring Club Italiano, (1994), Milano. 21 Treccani, Atlante Storico, Istituto della Enciclopedia italiana, (2007), Roma. Treccani, Enciclopedie, Treccani, Istituto della Enciclopedia italiana, (1949), Roma. Voigtländer, Nico, and Hans-Joachim Voth, “Persecution Perpetuated: The Medieval Origins of Anti-Semitic Violence in Nazi Germany,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 127, No. 3(2012), pp: 1339-1392. Williamson O. “The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead” in Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 38, No. 3(2000), pp: 595-613. 22 Table 1. Variables description The table provides a summary description of the variables. Details on the definitions and sources are available in the online Appendix. Variable name Description Source Number of non-profit organizations Total number of non-profit organizations (sum of voluntary associations, social cooperatives and foundations, excluding church based organizations) in the city scaled by population in the city. ISTAT (National Statistical Institute), 2001 census Cheating in math Mean index of cheating in the city standardized with its standard deviation. Based on the city-level indicator of cheating in math computed by INVALSI (a government agency for the evaluation of public schools) for the 2009 INVALSI test among the population of grade 8 Italian students. INVALSI (2014), 2009 grade 8 test Presence of an organ donation organization Indicator of existence of an organ donation organization in the city Ministero del Lavoro (2005). Medal of honor Indicator = 1 if the city has been awarded a gold medal for the heroism of its population in fighting against the Nazi-Fascists in the 1943-1945 period. ANPI, Resistenzaitaliana.it, http://www.storiaxxisecolo.it/documenti/documenti12.ht ml Commune (free city state) Indicator variable equal to 1 if the town was a commune based on two maps (see Online Appendix, Figures A1 and A2). The first reports the list of communes, around the time of the war between the communal cities and Emperor Frederick I (year 1167), the second around year 1300, at the pick of the communal experience. De Agostini (2007) Length of independence Difference between the year independence was lost and the year it was first acquired. Treccani (1949); when not available, we relied on the Touring Club Italiano (2000) and the historical summary on the official web page of the various cities. City belonged to the Lombard League Identifier = 1 for a commune that belonged to the Lombard League; see Figure A1 De Agostini (2007) City belonged to the Lombard League Identifier = 1 for a commune that was allied to the Emperor Frederick I; see Figure A1 De Agostini (2007) Ease of coordination Indicator = 1 when the city was a seat of a Bishop before 1000 C.E. Treccani (2007), Volume I, maps n. 152, 153, 154, 155 New seat of a Bishop after 1400 C.E. This variable is equal to 1 if a city has become a bishop city after year 1400, roughly after the end of the communal experience. Identified from the full list of the Italian Bishop cities as listed in the following link http://it.wikipedia.org/wiki/Elenco_delle_diocesi_italiane Size of city in year 1300 C.E. Indicators for city size around year 1300; Large is a dummy equal to 1 if the city population exceeds 10,000 people; Medium is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the city population is between 1,000 and 10,000 people. Bairoch, Batou and Chevre (1988, pp. 40-49) City located at an intersection of Roman roads Indicator equal to 1 if the city is located on a relevant Roman road or at the intersection between two or more Roman roads. Authors calculations. Roman roads are identified from the Touring Club Italiano (1994) Current location of Roman cities is obtained comparing today location of the city using Google Maps with the map of the Roman cities. 25 City located more than 5 kilometers from the sea 0.03 0 0.14 0 1 Population after unification in 1871 (in millions) 0.002 0.003 0.009 0.0003 0.026 Current Population 2001 (in millions) 0.0062 0.0023 0.027 0.00013 0.061 Panel D. Economic Variables (Center-North sample; N = 5,372) Mean Median Standard deviation 1st percentile 99th percentile Disposable income per capita (‘000 euros) 13.26 13.24 2.30 8.05 18.95 Gini land ownership inequality index 0.56 0.58 0.18 0.12 0.94 Gini income inequality index 0.38 0.38 0.04 0.30 0.50 Panel E. Historical variables that predict Commune (Center-North sample; N = 5,372) Mean Median Standard deviation 1st percentile 99th percentile Ease of coordination 0.033 0 0.18 0 1 City population above 10,000 in 1300 C.E.? (Yes = 1) 0.006 0 0.08 0 0 City population btw 1,000 and 10,000 in 1300 C.E.? (Yes = 1) 0.004 0 0.06 0 0 New seat of a Bishop after 1400 C.E. (Yes = 1) 0.006 0 0.08 0 0 Panel F. Summary statistics for then sample of largest Center-North 400 cities at unifications (N = 400) Mean Median Standard deviation 1st percentile 99th percentile Number of non-profit organizations (per 1,000 people) 5.58 4.29 11.86 0.95 22.3 City has an organ donation association? (Yes = 1) 0.04 0 0.20 0 1 Cheating in math 2.34 1.22 9.00 0.37 21.2 Free city 0.15 0 0.35 0 1 Altitude 0.35 0.29 0.30 0.004 2.63 City located on the coast 0.08 0.0 0.27 0 1 City located more than 5 kilometers from the sea 0.03 0 1.18 0 1 City located at intersection of Roman roads 0.108 0 0..31 0 1 Current Population 2001 (million people) 0.007 0.002 0.028 0.00014 0.068 26 Gini land ownership inequality index 0.60 0.60 0.17 0.15 0.94 Gini income inequality index 0.38 0.37 0.04 0.28 0.49 City was a Roman colony 0.05 0 0.22 0 1 City was on the itinerary of the emperor 0.06 0 0.23 0 1 City belonged to a marches 0.21 0 0.09 0 1 City population above 10,000 in 1300 C.E.? (Yes = 1) 0.006 0 0.076 0 0 City population between 1,000 and 10,000 people in 1300 C.E.? (Yes=1) 0.006 0 0.08 0 0 Panel G. The South sample (N = 2,175) Mean Median Standard deviation 1st percentile 99th percentile Number of non-profit organizations (per 1,000 people) 3.49 3.08 2.02 0.64 10.38 City has organ donation association? (Yes = 1) 0.042 0.00 0.20 0.00 1.0 Cheating in math 2.58 1.14 10.87 0.43 24.16 Elevation 0.40 0.39 0.28 0.004 1.17 Max difference in elevation within city territory 0.70 0.62 0.51 0.013 2.29 Ease of coordination 0.07 0 0.25 0 1 City population above 10K in 1300 C.E.? (Yes = 1) 0.006 0 0.08 0 0 City population btw 1,000 and 10,000 in 1300 C.E.? (Yes = 1) 0.019 0 0.14 0 1 City is on the coast 0.177 0.38 0 1 City is more than 5 km from the coast Current population 2001 (million people) 0.008 0.03 0.00 0.08 Gini income inequality index 0.366 0.04 0.27 0.45 Gini inequality index of land ownership 0.635 0.15 0.24 0.94 27 Table 3. Effect of communal history on civic capital The table shows OLS estimates of the effect of having been an independent city on measures of civic capital in the sample of all Italian cities in the Center-North. In Panel A the left hand side variable is the number of non-profit organizations per inhabitant in the city; in Panel B it is an indicator of cheating in math among the grade 8 students in the city; in Panel C it is a dummy for the existence of an organ donation organization (AIDO) in the city. Regressions are weighted using city population. Regressions are run on the whole sample of cities located in the Center-North of Italy. ***significant at less than 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. Panel A: Number of non-profit organizations Whole sample Whole sample No large towns No provincial capitals Whole sample Whole sample Commune 2.04*** 1.84*** 1.77*** 1.86*** 1.53*** 1.84*** (0.34) (0.33) (0.37) (0.42) (0.28) (0.26) Elevation 1.94*** 1.97*** 1.65*** 1.64*** 2.36*** 3.21*** (0.51) (0.50) (0.51) (0.55) (0.45) (0.54) Max difference in elevation 1.43*** 1.39*** 1.54*** 1.51*** 1.35*** 1.19*** (0.24) (0.24) (0.21) (0.24) (0.22) (0.23) City is on the coast 0.34 0.25 0.35 0.69*** 0.61** 0.60** (0.33) (0.31) (0.24) (0.23) (0.24) (0.27) City is more than 5km from the coast 0.96 1.08* 1.22** 1.34** 1.50** 0.97 (0.63) (0.64) (0.62) (0.61) (0.62) (0.64) Current Population 2001 -3.49 -4.22* -59.86*** -63.42*** -6.93*** -4.10** (2.73) (2.47) (9.85) (8.25) (1.84) (1.88) Current Population squared 1.43 1.41 622.40*** 441.95*** 3.11** 1.73 (2.05) (1.83) (110.56) (90.54) (1.37) (1.39) Gini inequality index of Land ownership 0.65 0.34 0.23 1.22** -0.01 (0.55) (0.38) (0.33) (0.48) (0.46) Gini income inequality index 10.02*** 9.61*** 7.63*** 0.56 9.58*** (2.22) (1.75) (1.50) (2.24) (1.91) Income per capita 0.35*** (0.04) Area dummies NO NO NO NO NO YES R-squared 0.08 0.08 0.09 0.08 0.10 0.10 Observations 5,360 5,360 5,341 5,298 5,360 5,360 30 C. Alternative definition of commune (combined definition) Non-profit organizations Organ donation organization Cheating in math Commune: combined definition 2.18*** 0.45*** -0.31*** (0.27) (0.06) (0.08) STANDARD CONTROLS YES YES YES Observations 5,360 5,372 1,890 R-squared 0.09 0.55 0.02 D. Historical measure of civic capital: medal of honor to the city Whole Center-North sample Whole Center-North Sample, No province capitals Sample 400 largest northern cities Commune 0.24*** 0.16** 0.22*** (0.075) (0.083) (0.075) STANDARD CONTROLS YES YES YES Observations 5,372 5,310 403 R-squared 0.724 0.167 0.724 31 Table 5: Digging deeper into history Panel A shows the second stage results of a two-step Heckman estimates of the effect of the length of independence of free cities on civic capital today. The first stage uses an indicator for whether the city was the seat of a bishop and whether it was founded by the Etruscans to achieve identification. The Mill’s ratio is obtained from the first-step probit regression. In Panel B we insert an indicator variable for whether the city evolved into an independent Signoria as an additional regressor. In Panel C we decompose the commune indicator variable depending on whether the commune was “neutral,” “allied with the Emperor” or “belonging to the Lombard League” in the war for independence against Emperor Frederick I. Regressions are run on the sample of all cities located in the Center-North. All regressions include the standard controls of Table 2, second column. For brevity they are not reported. The regressions with all controls are reported in Appendix, Table A2. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. *** significant at less than 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. Panel A. Effect of the length of independence on civic capital Non-profit organiz. Organ donation organiz. Cheating in math Log of length of independence 0.23** 0.09*** -0.11*** (0.09) (0.02) (0.03) STANDARD CONTROLS YES YES YES (1.57) (0.35) (0.53) Mill’s ratio -0.89*** 0.01 0.12 (0.29) (0 .07) (0.10) F-test for the exclusion restriction in selection equation 99.8 100.8 95.7 Observations 5,353 5,519 5,519 Panel B: The role of Signoria Non-profit organiz. Organ donation organiz. Cheating in math Commune 1.48*** 0.36*** -0.19** (0.32) (0.07) (0.08) Signoria 1.21*** 0.14** 0.01 (0.31) (0.07) (0.11) STANDARD CONTROLS YES YES YES Observations 5,344 5,538 1,911 R-squared 0.09 0.54 0.02 Panel C: The role of the Lombard League Non-profit organiz. Organ donation organiz. Cheating in math Neutral city 1.62*** 0.39*** -0.41** (0.41) (0.08) (0.18) Part of the Lombard League 2.48*** 0.50*** -0.10 (0.33) (0.06) (0.16) Allied to Emperor Fredrick I 1.11** 0.27** -0.09 (0.49) (0.12) (0.17) STANDARD CONTROLS YES YES YES Observations 5,360 5,538 1,912 R-squared 0.09 0.55 0.02 32 Table 6: Running a counterfactual Panel A shows regressions of social capital in the Center-North (first three columns) and in the South (last four columns) controlling for a proxy for ease of coordination (cities with a bishop seat at the time of the communes); Panel B reports estimates of social capital in the Center-North sample controlling for cities that became seat of a bishop after 1400 C.E. In Panel A, columns (1) and (6) and in Panel B columns (1)-(3) social capital is measured with the number of non-profit organizations per 1000 inhabitants. Columns (2) and (5) of panel A and (4)-(6) of Panel B measure the referenda turnout and columns (3) and (6) of Panel A and (7)-(9) of Panel B with the existence of an organ donation organizations. Post medieval bishop city is equal to 1 if a bishop city was created after 1400 C.E. and zero otherwise. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** significant at less than 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. A. Regressions of social capital in the Center-North and in the South Center-North sample South sample (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Non-profit org. Organ donation org. Cheating in math Non-profit org. Organ donation org. Cheating in math: Ease of coordination 1.61** 0.47*** -0.62*** 0.18 0.19*** -0.04 (0.219) (0.047) (0.097) (0.137) (0.065) (0.309) Elevation 1.93*** -0.25*** 0.92** 1.43*** -0.04 0.72 (0.475) (0.062) (0.433) (0.257) (0.083) (0.541) Max difference in elevation 1.35*** 0.01 0.26* -0.08 -0.05* 0.06 within city territory (0.219) (0.026) (0.144) (0.084) (0.029) (0.145) City is on the coast -0.27 -0.08* 0.02 0.23** -0.02 0.13 (0.264) (0.046) (0.118) (0.115) (0.044) (0.108) City is more than 5km 1.10* 0.07 -0.21 0.02 -0.03 1.46 from the coast (0.634) (0.072) (0.228) (0.143) (0.048) (1.098) Current Population -3.38*** 1.48*** -1.68*** -9.11*** 1.10* -3.50 (1.886) (0.290) (0.454) (2.242) (0.582) (2.849) Current Populations squared 1.03 -1.12*** 1.75*** 6.23*** -0.86* 4.47 (1.423) (0.218) (0.418) (1.924) (0.469) (2.816) Gini income inequality index 0.08 0.04 0.04 3.49** 2.05*** -21.66*** (0.449) (0.076) (0.437) (1.505) (0.547) (5.646) Gini inequality index of 9.83*** 2.17*** -8.51*** 1.61*** 0.35*** 1.75 land ownership (1.883) (0.377) (2.305) (0.351) (0.098) (1.330) Observations 5,357 5,535 1,911 2,175 2,178 1,210 R-squared 0.083 0.587 0.023 0.329 0.574 0.027
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved