Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Nos. 19-1231, 19-1241 In The Petitioners, v. Respondents ..., Study Guides, Projects, Research of Communication

PROMETHEUS RADIO PROJECT, ET AL. Respondents. On Writs of Certiorari to the. United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit. BRIEF FOR ...

Typology: Study Guides, Projects, Research

2021/2022

Uploaded on 07/05/2022

paul.kc
paul.kc 🇦🇺

4.7

(64)

1K documents

1 / 80

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download Nos. 19-1231, 19-1241 In The Petitioners, v. Respondents ... and more Study Guides, Projects, Research Communication in PDF only on Docsity! Nos. 19-1231, 19-1241 In The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION, ET AL., Petitioners, v. PROMETHEUS RADIO PROJECT, ET AL. Respondents. NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF BROADCASTERS, ET AL., Petitioners, v. PROMETHEUS RADIO PROJECT, ET AL. Respondents. On Writs of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit BRIEF FOR RESPONDENTS PROMETHEUS RADIO PROJECT, ET AL. Cheryl A. Leanza BEST BEST & KRIEGER LLP 1800 K Street. NW Suite 725 Washington, DC 20006 Ruthanne M. Deutsch Counsel of Record Hyland Hunt DEUTSCH HUNT PLLC 300 New Jersey Ave. NW Suite 900 Washington, DC 20001 (202) 868-6915 rdeutsch@deutschhunt.com Counsel for Prometheus Radio Project, et al. [Additional counsel listed on signature page] (i) QUESTION PRESENTED Section 202(h) of the Telecommunications Act directs the Federal Communications Commission to periodically review its broadcast ownership rules to “determine whether any of such rules are necessary in the public interest as the result of competition.” Based on that public-interest determination, the Commission must “repeal or modify any regulation … no longer in the public interest.” For decades, including in its most recent review at issue here, the Commission has maintained that ownership diversity—including race- and gender-ownership diversity—is a component of the public interest that it must consider when evaluating its ownership rules. The question presented is: Whether the Third Circuit correctly deferred to the Commission’s consistent interpretation that ownership diversity is an important aspect of the public interest served by its broadcast ownership rules, and correctly held that the Commission acted arbitrarily and capriciously in repealing most of those rules without any reasoned analysis of the repeal’s likely impact on ownership diversity. iv A.  Section 202(h)’s Text Confirms that the Public Interest Is Paramount. ....................... 27  B.  Congress Accepted a Broad Public- Interest Standard when Amending § 202(h). ......................................................... 29  II.  The Commission’s About-Face Conclusion That Relaxing Ownership Rules Would Not Harm Ownership Diversity Was Arbitrary And Capricious. ......................................................... 30  A.  The Reconsideration Order Rests on an Unreasoned Reinterpretation of the Same Facts, Not a Transparent and Reasoned Policy Choice. ............................... 31  B.  The Commission’s Ownership- Diversity Findings Are Irrational. .............. 36  C.  The Commission’s Decision Rested on an Arbitrary Assessment of the Past, Not a Reasoned Predictive Judgment. ........ 43  D. Nothing in § 202(h) Exempts the Commission from the Ordinary APA Requirement to Show Its Work. .................. 48  III.  The Third Circuit’s Remedy Was Correct. ....... 51  CONCLUSION .......................................................... 56  Appendix — Statutory Addendum ............................ 1a v TABLE OF AUTHORITIES Cases  Allied-Signal, Inc. v. U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Comm'n, 988 F.2d 146 (D.C. Cir. 1993) ................................ 51 Am. Great Lakes Ports Ass'n v. Schultz, 962 F.3d 510 (D.C. Cir. 2020) ................................ 52 Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1 (1945) ...................................................... 4 Bowen v. Am. Hosp. Ass’n, 476 U.S. 610 (1986) ................................................ 40 Castañeda-Castillo v. Holder, 638 F.3d 354 (1st Cir. 2011) .................................. 53 Cellco P'ship v. FCC, 357 F.3d 88 (D.C. Cir. 2004) .............................. 8, 27 Ctr. for Auto Safety v. Fed. Highway Admin., 956 F.2d 309 (D.C. Cir. 1992) ................................ 33 Dep’t of Commerce v. New York, 139 S. Ct. 2551 (2019) ............................................ 36 Dep’t of Homeland Sec. v. Regents of Univ. of Cal., 140 S. Ct. 1891 (2020) ............................................ 54 vi Dist. Hosp. Partners, L.P. v. Burwell, 786 F.3d 46 (D.C. Cir. 2015) .................................. 44 Encino Motorcars, LLC v. Navarro, 136 S. Ct. 2117 (2016) ...................................... 42, 43 FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 556 U.S. 502 (2009) ................................................ 43 FCC v. Nat’l Citizens Comm. for Broad., 436 U.S. 775 (1978) ........................................ passim FCC v. WNCN Listeners Guild, 450 U.S. 582 (1981) .................................... 31, 32, 35 Fox Television Stations, Inc. v. FCC, 280 F.3d 1027 (D.C. Cir. 2002) ...................... passim Fox Television Stations, Inc. v. FCC, 293 F.3d 537 (D.C. Cir. 2002) .................................. 7 Gundy v. United States, 139 S. Ct. 2116 (2020) ............................................ 26 Kisor v. Wilkie, 139 S. Ct. 2400 (2019) ............................................ 36 Lamar, Archer & Cofrin, LLP v. Appling, 138 S. Ct. 1752 (2018) ............................................ 30 ix Statutes Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56 (1996) .......... passim 28 U.S.C. § 2342(1) .................................................... 54 47 U.S.C. § 151 ...................................................... 8, 28 47 U.S.C. § 161 .................................................. 2, 8, 27 47 U.S.C. § 257 ............................................................ 8 47 U.S.C. § 257(b) ...................................................... 28 47 U.S.C. § 303 ........................................................ 1, 3 47 U.S.C. § 309(i) ................................................... 5, 28 47 U.S.C. § 309(j) ................................................... 5, 28 Regulations   47 C.F.R. § 73.3555 ...................................................... 9 Legislative Materials   H.R. Rep. No. 97-765 (1982) (Conf. Rep.) ................. 28 x Agency Materials   1998 Biennial Regulatory Review, 15 F.C.C.R. 11058 (2000) ................................. 10, 38 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review, 18 F.C.C.R. 13620 (2003) ............................... passim 2006 Quadrennial Regulatory Review, 23 F.C.C.R. 2010 (2008) ......................................... 12 2014 Quadrennial Regulatory Review, 29 F.C.C.R. 4371 (2014) ......................................... 14 2018 Quadrennial Regulatory Review, 33 F.C.C.R. 12111 (2018) ......................................... 6 Amendment of Section 73.3555 of the Commission’s Rules Relating to Multiple Ownership of AM, FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 100 FCC 2d 74 (1985) ........................................ 5, 32 Fourth Report on Ownership of Broadcast Stations, 35 F.C.C.R. 1217 (2020) ........................................... 6 Policies and Rules Regarding Minority and Female Ownership of Mass Media Facilities, 10 F.C.C.R. 2788 (1995) ................................... 4, 5, 6 xi Promoting Diversification of Ownership in the Broadcasting Services, 23 F.C.C.R. 5922 (2008) ................................... 13, 31 Promoting Diversification of Ownership in the Broadcasting Services, 24 F.C.C.R. 5896 (2009) ......................................... 15 Review of the Commission’s Regulations Governing Television Broadcasting, 10 F.C.C.R. 3524 (1995) ................................... 3, 4, 5 Review of the Commission’s Regulations Governing Television Broadcasting, 14 F.C.C.R. 12903 (1999) ....................................... 10 Other Authorities   Commissioner Starks Statement on Fourth Broadcast Station Ownership Report (Feb. 14, 2020) ...................... 7 David Honig, How the FCC Suppressed Minority Broadcast Ownership, and How the FCC Can Undo the Damage It Caused, 12 S. J. Pol’y & Just. 44 (2018) .......................................................... 6 Leadership Conf. on Civil & Human Rights, Summary of FCC Data (Dec. 2020) ................... 7, 39 Richard J. Pierce, Jr. & Kristin E. Hickman, Administrative Law Treatise § 11.9 (6th ed. 2020) ....................................................................... 51 3 reasonable analysis of the record showed that past deregulation caused harm. Because the Commission provided no reasoned analysis on this issue—which could have changed the Commission’s mind about repeal—the Third Circuit correctly vacated the Commission’s orders. That vacatur leaves the agency free to reach the same result on remand if it provides a reasoned basis for its assessment. STATEMENT OF THE CASE I. Legal Background. “Congress delegate[d] broad authority to the Commission to allocate broadcast licenses in the ‘public interest,’’’ FCC v. Nat’l Citizens Comm. for Broad., 436 U.S. 775, 815 (1978) (NCCB), and to regulate broadcast licensees as “public convenience, interest, or necessity requires,” 47 U.S.C. § 303. Under this mandate, the Commission has limited the number of radio or television stations a single party may own nationally or in local markets, and limited cross-ownership of broadcast stations and other media in defined markets. See, e.g., United States v. Storer Broad. Co., 351 U.S. 192, 202-05 (1956); NCCB, 436 U.S. at 793-802. The Commission has modified these rules over time to serve the public interest. See Review of the Commission’s Regulations Governing Television Broadcasting, 10 F.C.C.R. 3524, 3526-29 (1995) (1995 Television Rule) (summarizing changes). Ownership limits have always aimed to “avoid overconcentration of broadcasting facilities,” Storer Broad., 351 U.S. at 4 193, because “diversification of mass media ownership serves the public interest by promoting diversity of program and service viewpoints, as well as by preventing undue concentration of economic power.” NCCB, 436 U.S. at 780. The Commission’s public- interest mandate regarding broadcast ownership is reflected in three “traditional goals”: “competition, diversity, and localism in broadcast services.” 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review, 18 F.C.C.R. 13620, 13624 (2003) (2002 Review). A. The Historic Public Interest in Broadcast Ownership Diversity. 1. The “public interest” “necessarily invites reference to First Amendment principles,” NCCB, 436 U.S. at 795, including “that the widest possible dissemination of information from diverse and antagonistic sources is essential to the welfare of the public,” Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1, 20 (1945). Ensuring diversity “in the material presented over the airways,” then, has been “[t]raditionally[] at least as important as the Commission’s concern about undue economic concentration among broadcast stations.” 1995 Television Rule, 10 F.C.C.R. at 3547. The Commission’s ownership rules provide a content- neutral means of promoting viewpoint diversity. See NCCB, 436 U.S. at 801-02. The Commission has consistently recognized that “the public interest is served by increasing economic opportunities for minorities and women to own communications facilities.” Policies and Rules Regarding Minority and Female Ownership of Mass Media Facilities, 10 F.C.C.R. 2788, 2788-90 (1995) 5 (1995 Ownership Diversity). This is consistent with “core” Commission goals: “maximizing the diversity of points of view available to the public over the mass media,” and “promoting competition” which is fostered by new market entrants with different perspectives. Id. The Commission continues to espouse the principle that “our media landscape should be diverse because our population is diverse.” JA104. 2. Often at Congress’s direction, the Commission has adopted rules to foster diverse ownership opportunities. See, e.g., 1995 Ownership Diversity, 10 F.C.C.R. at 2788-90 (describing “incentives to owners of broadcast and cable television properties to sell their stations to minorities”); 47 U.S.C. § 309(j)(4)(C) (requiring measures to “promote … economic opportunity for a wide variety of applicants, including ... businesses owned by members of minority groups and women” in spectrum auctions); id. § 309(i)(3)(A). The Commission’s ownership rules—particularly its local rules—are key instruments for its ownership- diversity goal. Such “local ownership limits,” as opposed to national ones, are most “pertinent to assuring a diversity of views,” because the “most important idea markets are local.” Amendment of Section 73.3555 [formerly Sections 73.35, 73.240 and 73.636] of the Commission’s Rules Relating to Multiple Ownership of AM, FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 100 FCC 2d 74, 82 (1985) (1985 National Television Rule). In setting local ownership rules (like those at issue here), the Commission has consistently considered not only the effect of new media forms on competition, e.g., 1995 Television Rule, 10 F.C.C.R. at 3531, but also the effect of any proposed consolidation 8 regulation … no longer in the public interest.” Id. at 112. Section 202(h) did not alter the Commission’s longstanding interpretation of the public interest. “[N]othing in § 202(h) signals a departure from [the] historic scope” of the Commission’s public-interest authority, including the public-interest inquiry’s “historical[] embrace[] of diversity (as well as localism).” Fox I, 280 F.3d at 1042. The statute “mandates that a rule [determined] necessary ‘in the public interest’—including the public interest in diversity—be retained.” Id. at 1041. Elsewhere in the 1996 Act, Congress confirmed the breadth of the public-interest mandate and its commitment to race and gender diversity. See 47 U.S.C. §§ 151, 257. Nor does § 202(h) require deregulation at all costs. For § 202(h), like the cross-referenced § 11, any “deregulatory presumption arises only after [the Commission] has determined … that a regulation is no longer necessary in the public interest.” Cellco P’ship v. FCC, 357 F.3d 88, 99 (D.C. Cir. 2004). In both provisions, the Commission must first “determine whether its then-extant rules remain useful in the public interest; if no longer useful, they must be repealed or modified.” Prometheus Radio Project v. FCC, 373 F.3d 372, 395 (3d Cir. 2004) (Prometheus I); accord Fox I, 280 F.3d at 1043-44; Sinclair Broad. Grp., Inc. v. FCC, 284 F.3d 148, 162-64 (D.C. Cir. 2002). Section 202(h) thus does not operate as a “one- way ratchet,” Prometheus I, 373 F.3d at 394. Despite its “admittedly deregulatory tenor, the statute does not foreclose the possibility of increased regulation” during the review process “if the Commission finds 9 such action in the public interest.” Id. at 444 (Scirica, J., partially concurring). Whether the Commission repeals, modifies, or retains a rule, “it must do so in the public interest and support its decision with a reasoned analysis.” Id. at 395. C. The FCC’s Continued Commitment to Diversity within § 202(h) Reviews. Four local ownership rules are relevant here: the local television rule, which governs how many stations may be jointly owned in the same local market, 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(b) (2017); the local radio rule, which does the same for radio, id. § 73.3555(a); the newspaper/ broadcasting cross-ownership rule, which limits ownership of a daily newspaper and broadcast station in the same local market, id. § 73.3555(d); and the radio/television cross-ownership rule, which caps the number of same-market television and radio stations that may be jointly owned, id. § 73.3555(c). Whether opting to retain, tighten, or relax these limits, the statutory public-interest standard has, as the text demands, been the Commission’s polestar. Through every § 202(h) review, the Commission’s stated commitment to ownership diversity as part of the public interest—in service of viewpoint diversity and competition, and to better serve local communities by fostering more representative use of the spectrum—has been unwavering. 1. First Reviews. In 1999-2000, the Commission completed two reviews: one for local television, mandated by Congress in § 202(c); the second, its first (then-biennial) review under § 202(h). 10 The § 202(c) review relaxed the local television and television/radio cross-ownership rules. Review of the Commission’s Regulations Governing Television Broadcasting, 14 F.C.C.R. 12903, 12907-08 (1999) (1999 Television Review). “[S]har[ing] the[] concerns” that “greater consolidation of ownership in broadcasting makes it more difficult for new entrants,” “particularly … for minorities and women,” id. at 12909-10, the Commission promised to monitor the effect of relaxing the rules on ownership diversity. Id. at 12910. The Commission also adopted the failing station solicitation rule, conditioning certain ownership-limit waivers on the seller soliciting out-of- market buyers, to give “minorities and women … an opportunity to bid.” Id. at 12936-37. The first § 202(h) review largely retained the remaining pre-existing rules. See 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review, 15 F.C.C.R. 11058, 11061 (2000) (2000 Order). The Commission noted “a drop in the number of minority-owned broadcast stations” following deregulatory changes. See id. at 11073. It also reiterated the need for further study of how ownership limits affected ownership diversity. Id. at 11084. The D.C. Circuit found that aspects of both reviews failed to meet APA standards. See Fox I, 280 F.3d at 1043-44; Sinclair Broad., 284 F.3d at 162. 2.a. 2002 Review. The 2002 Review left the local radio rule largely unchanged but relaxed limits on local television ownership. 18 F.C.C.R. at 13668, 13712. For cross-ownership, the Commission replaced the newspaper/broadcast and radio/television rules with new “cross-media” limits that prohibited, limited, or permitted cross-ownership based on market size. Id. 13 businesses” to “strengthen the diverse and robust marketplace of ideas.” Promoting Diversification of Ownership in the Broadcasting Services, 23 F.C.C.R. 5922, 5924-25 (2008) (Diversity Order). b. In Prometheus Radio Project v. FCC, 652 F.3d 431 (3d Cir. 2011) (Prometheus II), the Third Circuit unanimously upheld the FCC’s decisions regarding the local television, local radio, and radio/television cross-ownership rules. The panel majority found, however, that the Commission failed to adequately notice its changes to the newspaper/broadcast cross- ownership rule. Id. at 445-46, 453. Given the FCC’s avowed purpose—“increasing broadcast ownership by minorities and women,” id. at 469—the unanimous court also held that the Diversity Order had not reasonably explained how the revenue- based eligible-entity definition would further that goal. Id. at 471. The court noted that the Commission referenced virtually no data on ownership by women and people of color because, “as the Commission has since conceded, it has no accurate data to cite.” Id. at 470. Because “[p]romoting broadcast ownership by minorities and women is, in the FCC’s own words, ‘a long-standing policy goal of the Commission,’” the Third Circuit urged the Commission to “gather[] the information required to address these challenges.” Id. at 472. Judge Scirica agreed, dissenting only on the newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership notice issue. Id. at 473-75. 14 II. The 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review. A. Commission Delay. The FCC failed to produce a decision in the 2010 Quadrennial Review. Instead, in 2014, the FCC initiated the 2014 Review and rolled the 2010 Review into that proceeding. 2014 Quadrennial Regulatory Review, 29 F.C.C.R. 4371 (2014) (2014 Notice) (excerpts at JA58-100). Petitions for review were originally assigned to the D.C. Circuit. After reviewing the briefs, and with the Commission’s support, the D.C. Circuit transferred the case to the Third Circuit. Prometheus Radio Project v. FCC, 824 F.3d 33, 39 (3d Cir. 2016) (Prometheus III). The Third Circuit heard challenges to the Commission’s delay in completing the 2010 Review, including delay in reconsidering the eligible-entity definition remanded in Prometheus II. The court also reviewed, and vacated, the FCC’s rule tightening ownership limits by expanding its ownership attribution policy (which treats certain contractual arrangements as controlling ownership interests), because such tightening could not lawfully occur until after the mandated public-interest determination under § 202(h). Id. at 59-60. As to the eligible-entity definition, the court instructed the Commission to “act promptly” to finally determine “whether to adopt a new definition,” stating, “[i]f it needs more data to do so, it must get it.” Id. at 49. The court disclaimed any “inten[t] to prejudge the outcome of this analysis; we only order that it must be completed.” Id. at 49. The court also instructed the Commission to “consider how the 15 ongoing broadcast incentive auction affects minority and female ownership.” Id. at 54 n.13.2 B. The Record Before the Commission. Responding to the 2014 Notice, commenters explained that longstanding problems with the Commission’s data on ownership diversity made it difficult to analyze trends over time. The Commission had itself in 2009 recognized major flaws in data drawn from Form 323, the agency’s mandatory licensee reporting form. See Promoting Diversification of Ownership in the Broadcasting Services, 24 F.C.C.R. 5896, 5897-98 (2009). Commenters elaborated that the data continued to have significant gaps; exhorted the FCC to enforce existing data-submission requirements and expand the requirements to non-commercial stations; and urged that the data be made available to the public in a usable format. See, e.g., CA3JA944-46. Commenters also pointed to existing studies that had made reasonable efforts to correct the data, urging the Commission to do the same. See, e.g., Comments of Nat’l Hispanic Media Coalition, FCC Dkt. 14-50, at 17 (Aug. 6, 2014). One study, undertaken by Free Press, evaluated how loosening local television rules in the 1990s affected ownership diversity. CA3JA548.3 Free 2 The incentive auction was designed to free spectrum for wireless data companies. JA176. Participating broadcasters could relinquish their spectrum for an incentive payment and either go off air or share a single channel with another station. Remaining stations were relocated to clear spectrum bands. Id. 3 S. Derek Turner & Mark Cooper, Out of the Picture 2007: Minority & Female TV Station Ownership in the United States (Oct. 2007), https://www.freepress.net/policy-library/free-press- report-out-picture. 18 attempted to examine the effect of relaxing its ownership rules in the 1990s, working with two datasets: 1990s-era data from the NTIA and the Commission’s own Form 323 data from a decade later, but with no attempt to make the different data sets comparable. See JA174-75 (television); JA215-16 (radio). For both radio and television, the raw data showed a steep decline in ownership by people of color following relaxation of the ownership limits. Id. The Commission failed to acknowledge the diversity drop following relaxation (and ignored the Free Press study on that point), focusing only on how Form 323 data showed higher station ownership by people of color many years later. Id. The FCC recognized that drawing trends from the disparate datasets was unreliable, as changes in the data did not necessarily reflect “actual changes in the marketplace,” JA174 n.211, and there was no NTIA “data on female ownership,” id.; see also JA215 nn.325-26. While still using this analysis to justify refusing to tighten its rules, the FCC concluded the analysis did not support relaxing them, because there was “no evidence in the record that would permit [it] to infer” that the 1990s relaxation caused the eventual increase in diverse ownership. JA176; JA216-17. Ultimately, considering the record as a whole, the FCC concluded that retaining the rules was necessary for the public interest and would promote ownership diversity. See, e.g., JA171-72. Conceding continued data flaws, the FCC described efforts that it hoped would “improve the quality of its broadcast ownership data” going forward. JA361-69. Buttressing the Commission’s decision to largely retain the ownership rules was its recognition 19 that the broadcasting industry was “on the precipice of great change” given the ongoing incentive auction that would change licensees’ use of broadcast television spectrum. JA104. The 2016 Order re-adopted the same revenue- based eligible-entity definition, explicitly broadening its purpose to foster entry by all small businesses. JA105. 2. Fifteen months later, a newly composed FCC issued the Reconsideration Order, App.65a-310a, relying upon the “same facts used by th[e] Commission just over a year ago to reach the exact opposite conclusions.” App.284a (Commissioner Clyburn, dissenting). 5 The Commission eliminated the cross- ownership limits entirely and significantly relaxed the local television ownership rules. App.68a-69a.6 The FCC did not alter its view that diversity, including ownership diversity, remained an important aspect of the public interest. See, e.g., App.86a-87a & n.49. To the contrary, the Commission affirmed its policy goals of “viewpoint diversity, localism, and competition,” and declined to consider “arguments that ownership does not influence viewpoint.” Id. Rather than disavowing its long-held ownership- diversity goal, the new Commission rested its decision on a changed assessment of the same record. The 2016 Order had concluded that retaining the rules would 5 App. cites are to the Petition Appendix in No. 19-1241. 6 Local television rule relaxations eliminated the prohibition allowing ownership of two same-market television stations only if eight independent voices would remain, App.147a-48a, and the rule counting certain television joint sales agreements as ownership (referred to as “attribution”), App.69a. 20 promote ownership diversity. The newly composed Commission found—based on the exact same race/gender ownership data—that retaining the rules would not help ownership diversity and loosening them would not cause any harm. See App.120a n.138; App.139a n.201. Finally, “to promote ownership diversity,” the Commission announced its intent to adopt a new “incubator program” “to help facilitate station ownership for a certain class of new owners” to be defined later. App.69a; App.207a-08a; App.216a. 3. The Commission’s subsequent Incubator Order adopted a radio-only program, defining eligible entities by revenue and new-entrant status. JA596-97; JA603-04. The program permitted incumbent radio broadcasters to obtain ownership-cap waivers in large markets after helping new broadcasters in much smaller markets. JA647. Commissioner Rosenworcel’s dissenting statement echoed various commenters’ concerns that the order’s “scope is too narrow, its consequences too small, and its impact on markets too muddled,” and that it was not “meaningful action[] to address the shameful lack of racial and gender diversity in broadcast station ownership.” JA703. III. The Third Circuit’s Decision. Petitions for review of the Reconsideration Order and the Incubator Order, initially assigned to the D.C. Circuit, were transferred by that court without opposition to the Third Circuit. The Third Circuit consolidated the cases with pending petitions for review of the 2016 Order. 23 I. Industry Petitioners contend, without support from the Government, that § 202(h) requires the Commission to consider only “competition, not minority and female ownership.” Br. 20. But § 202(h)’s text shows otherwise: It requires the Commission to determine whether its rules remain “necessary in the public interest as the result of competition.” That text requires the Commission to consider the effect of “competition”—that is, market conditions. But the lodestar of the inquiry remains the broader “public interest.” In the orders under review, the Commission hewed to its settled view that § 202(h) requires it to determine whether, as markets change, ownership rules remain necessary to serve the public interest— including the public-interest goal of ownership diversity. Section 202(h) plainly authorizes this longstanding interpretation, which Congress blessed when amending the statute without change to the public-interest standard in 2004. II. The Commission has long recognized that diverse ownership promotes competition and fosters greater diversity in viewpoints and programming— central goals of broadcast regulation. Ownership diversity, including diversity by race and gender, is not ancillary to the quadrennial review. It is central to the undertaking as the Commission has permissibly defined it. A. The Third Circuit’s decision permits the FCC to abandon this long-held view—if it does so with transparency and reasoned analysis. But the Commission cannot avoid accountability for a choice to deregulate regardless of public-interest harm by hiding behind a deeply flawed conclusion that 24 deregulation will not harm its long- (and still-) avowed ownership-diversity goal. B. The Commission’s conclusion that radical relaxation would not harm ownership diversity rests on three fundamental errors: an arbitrarily simplistic assessment of past rule changes that ignores record evidence; a complete failure to evaluate important aspects of the problem, including female ownership and the effect of the incentive auction; and a wholly unexplained change in position from its 2016 conclusion that the rules promote ownership diversity to the 2017 assertion on the same record that they do not. C. Deference to unreasoned predictions or excuses that the data were too difficult to produce cannot sustain the Commission’s orders. The agency’s failure here is not a failure of omniscience, but of thoroughness and rationality. Any “prediction” rested solely on an irrational no-harm finding grounded in the Commission’s own choice to rely on faulty data. Better analysis was possible based on the existing record: Commenters submitted well-reasoned empirical evidence (which the Commission ignored). D. Nothing about § 202(h) reviews justifies treating them differently from any other agency action. Section 202(h) mandates a primarily retrospective analysis, not a purely prospective one, and thus surely does not permit the Commission to change first and assess public-interest necessity later. Nor does the four-year cycle mitigate all harm caused by the Commission getting it wrong. Eggs cannot be unscrambled, and harm is not meaningfully ameliorated by a reversal in position four years (or, more likely, nearly a decade) later. 25 III. The Third Circuit properly vacated the orders given the seriousness of the defects in the Commission’s analysis and the disruption that would have resulted without vacatur, sensibly extending this standard APA remedy to all three interrelated orders. Any change in position regarding the effect of repeal on ownership diversity, following a reasoned analysis, would necessarily implicate not only the ownership rules but also programs implementing or varying those rules. Likewise, the Third Circuit’s retention of jurisdiction over the remand was consistent with settled practice. It does not conflict with venue provisions and does not consign review of future quadrennial reviews to the Third Circuit. Instructing agencies to re-do their irrational analyses is an administrative law commonplace—not a new impermissible procedural requirement. On remand, the Commission is free to decide that ownership diversity should no longer be part of the public interest under § 202(h), or that no matter how bad the effect on ownership diversity, other goals require repeal of its ownership rules. All the Third Circuit requires is what the APA demands: transparent policy choices and reasoned explanations. ARGUMENT I. The Plain Object Of § 202(h) Review Is The Public Interest. Whether retaining, enhancing, or relaxing its ownership rules, every § 202(h) review to date has recognized the centrality and breadth of the statute’s express public-interest goal. Industry Petitioners’ 28 The larger context of the 1996 Act confirms that Congress did not pursue deregulation at all costs. While passing various deregulatory measures, see id. at 1033, Congress also reaffirmed the “national policy” of “favoring diversity of media voices,” in a newly enacted provision mandating review of barriers to entry for small businesses, 47 U.S.C. § 257(b). And Congress augmented the Commission’s guiding directive to provide communication services to “all the people of the United States,” by including a mandate that services be provided “without discrimination on the basis of race, color, religion, national origin, or sex.” Id. § 151. Elsewhere, in provisions predating but surviving the 1996 Act, Congress explicitly prioritized ownership diversity. For spectrum auctions, Congress required the FCC to “promote economic opportunity for a wide variety of applicants, including small businesses, rural telephone companies, and businesses owned by members of minority groups and women,” 47 U.S.C. § 309(j)(4)(C), and to “consider the use of … bidding preferences” for “minority groups and women,” id. § 309(j)(4)(D); see also id. § 309(i)(3)(A) (requiring preference for minority owners under now- defunct program where licenses were assigned by lottery).8 8 In passing that provision, Congress recognized the need to “remedy[] the past economic disadvantage to minorities … while promoting the primary communications policy objective of achieving a greater diversification of the media of mass communications.” H.R. Rep. No. 97-765, at 44 (1982) (Conf. Rep.). 29 Industry Petitioners argue that these express targeted measures bar consideration of ownership diversity within § 202(h)’s public-interest inquiry. Br. 28-29. But specific measures do not implicitly constrain the Commission’s rulemaking authority in other broadly written provisions. This Court has rejected similar attempts at “interpretative gerrymander[ing].” Michigan, 576 U.S. at 754-55 (holding that specific provisions mentioning costs did not make cost irrelevant to a broad standard “encompassing multiple relevant factors (which include but are not limited to costs)”). B. Congress Accepted a Broad Public-Interest Standard when Amending § 202(h). Both before and after passage of § 202(h), including in every § 202(h) review to date, the Commission has steadfastly affirmed that ownership diversity serves the public interest. See supra at 4-13. Against this settled regulatory backdrop, when Congress enacted § 202(h), it nowhere even intimated an interest in cabining the breadth of the public- interest inquiry. And in amending §202(h) in 2004, Congress left intact the public-interest mandate, shortly after the Commission had reaffirmed that “diversity, competition, and localism” were “longstanding goals that would continue to be core agency objectives” in evaluating ownership rules, including “minority and female ownership diversity.” 2002 Review, 18 F.C.C.R. at 13627. “Congress is presumed to be aware of an administrative … interpretation of a statute and to adopt that interpretation when it re-enacts a statute without 30 change.” Lamar, Archer & Cofrin, LLP v. Appling, 138 S. Ct. 1752, 1762 (2018). And Congress was certainly aware here. While cementing the Commission’s interpretation of its public-interest mandate by leaving the key language intact, Congress’s 2004 amendment to § 202(h) tightened the caps on national television ownership rules from the Commission’s proposed 45% down to 39%, and removed those rules from the § 202(h) process. See Prometheus I, 373 F.3d at 388-89 (describing 2004 legislation). These legislative changes belie any Congressional endorsement of a deregulation-uber-alles approach or rejection of the Commission’s settled public-interest goals in § 202(h). As the Government agrees (Br. 18-19), nothing in the public-interest standard requires the Commission to give a single policy—including competition— “controlling weight in all circumstances.” NCCB, 436 U.S. at 810. Section 202(h) cannot plausibly be read to require a competition-only standard that the Commission has never endorsed. II. The Commission’s About-Face Conclusion That Relaxing Ownership Rules Would Not Harm Ownership Diversity Was Arbitrary And Capricious. When the Commission jettisoned a large swath of its rules, it rejected its own determination a year earlier—on the same record—that retaining the rules would promote ownership diversity. That about-face was arbitrary and capricious for multiple reasons. 33 in a rational (re)weighing of policies here: “The Commission might well be within its rights to adopt a new deregulatory framework (even if the rule changes would have some adverse effect on ownership diversity) if it … explained why it believed the trade- off was justified for other policy reasons.” App.41a. In short, to re-shuffle its policy goals, the Commission must be reasonable and transparent. That is not what happened here.10 Rather than transparently declaring ownership diversity less important than other goals, the Commission altered its rules on the (irrational) finding that ownership diversity would not be harmed, based on an “analysis” that failed several tests of reasonableness and “rest[ed] upon a factual premise … unsupported by substantial evidence.” Ctr. for Auto Safety v. Fed. Highway Admin., 956 F.2d 309, 314 (D.C. Cir. 1992) (Thomas, J.). 3. Before this Court, the Government seeks to distance itself from a central element of the decision on review. Citing “empirical uncertainty” on ownership diversity and substantial benefits for other aspects of the public interest, the Government now contends that the FCC simply made a “discretionary policy judgment” that the rules could not be retained based on “‘unsubstantiated hope that [they] will promote minority and female ownership.’” Br. 39 10 The Government highlights (Br. 30) a statement within the 2014 Notice tentatively declining to tighten local radio rules in part because ownership diversity was merely one of several competing goals and tightening purportedly would harm the others. JA79-80. That passage merely highlights the absence of any similar balancing in the Reconsideration Order. 34 (quoting App.140a). But the FCC’s decision is inextricably linked to its unreasoned no-harm findings, which are not “stray FCC statements taken out of context” (Br. 38), as the Government now says. The Reconsideration Order is strewn with assertions that repeal would “have no material effect on minority and female ownership.” App.88a; App.117a (same); App.138a (“record fails to demonstrate that eliminating the Radio/Television Cross-Ownership Rule is likely to harm minority and female ownership”); App.161a (“not likely to harm minority and female ownership”). Before the Third Circuit, the FCC insisted that it had “analyzed the question at length and determined that its rule changes were not likely to harm ownership diversity.” CA3 FCC Br. at 46-47. Everyone understood the order to make—and rest upon—this no-harm finding. E.g., Industry Br. 43; App.57a (Scirica, J.). In any event, the order is no less arbitrary when recast as a judgment that only “unsubstantiated hope,” App.140a, could link the rules with ownership diversity. Today’s “unsubstantiated hope” that retaining the rules would not foster ownership diversity was found true in 2016—on the same record. E.g., JA171-72 (although the rules were not retained “with the purpose of preserving or creating specific amounts of minority and female ownership, we find that retaining the existing rule[s] nevertheless promotes opportunities for diversity in local television ownership”); JA293; JA310 (same for cross-ownership rules). The “unsubstantiated hope” judgment thus contradicts the record just as the no-harm finding does—and is equally irrational. 35 Ultimately, there can be no reasoned weighing of competing policy goals if one factor has not been rationally considered. See WNCN, 450 U.S. at 595-96 (Commission’s position “reflect[ed] a reasonable accommodation” of two competing policy goals where it had “assessed the benefits and the harm likely to flow” from a proposed course of action); NCCB, 436 U.S. at 805-08 (deferring to a “rational prediction”). And if, because of faulty and incomplete data, “uncertainty is so profound that it precludes [the agency] from making a reasoned judgment … [the agency] must say so.” Massachusetts v. EPA, 549 U.S. 497, 534 (2007). In retaining the rules, the 2016 Commission did acknowledge data problems that precluded it from relying on the data to justify relaxing the rules. E.g., JA176. But there was no equivalent “say so” on reconsideration and the 2017 Commission’s jettisoning of the rules did not rest on “empirical uncertainty.” SG Br. 39. Instead, the FCC made an (arbitrary) judgment that repeal would not harm ownership diversity. The Government cannot retroactively transform that finding into a transparent reweighing of policy goals by invoking uncertainty. If the Commission’s view is that the ownership rules must go—no matter the effect on ownership diversity—because other benefits outweigh even the worst possible harm to diversity, it must reach that conclusion openly and rationally to survive APA review. Precisely because the “public interest” standard is a “supple instrument for the exercise of discretion,” WNCN, 450 U.S. at 593, administrative accountability demands transparency when an agency redefines the contours of that standard. 38 A similar radio station listing showed the same pattern—an immediate decrease after Congress relaxed the local radio rules in 1996 and higher numbers only years later. See JA215-16. From this mere listing of raw numbers drawn from disparate data sets, the FCC concluded that “minority ownership has grown since that [pre-1999 local television] rule was eliminated.” JA175. Even assuming (counterfactually) reliable data—that statement is true only in the same way that it is true that the economy has grown since the Great Depression. Any eventual improvements in ownership diversity after decimation following the 1990s rule changes do not disprove that relaxation harms ownership diversity. As the Third Circuit explained, the agency’s no-harm finding was arbitrary because the agency failed to assess “how many minority-owned stations there would have been in 2009 had there been no deregulation.” App.39a. Contrary to the Government’s argument (Br. 42- 43), no sophisticated regression analysis or other methodology is needed to understand why the agency’s simplistic conclusion is wrong. The rule change precipitated a decline, a simple fact the Commission has acknowledged in the past. See 2000 Order, 15 F.C.C.R. at 11084 (noting “a drop in the number of minority-owned broadcast stations” following deregulatory changes). Down does not mean up, and an increase years later does not erase the initial decline. If anything, the (slow) increase, during a period when some ownership limits remained in place as a bulwark against consolidation, could reinforce the importance of the local ownership rules for fostering 39 ownership diversity. And a better analysis was in the record. Free Press’s tracing analysis concluded that the 1990s television rule changes contributed to the loss of 40% of the previously minority-owned stations. CA3JA551. The Commission did not discredit this analysis; it simply ignored the Free Press study—a particularly egregious omission given that it cited the study for one of its data points. See JA175 & n.215. 2. Even when operating under a statutory standard that grants it flexibility, the Commission may not “entirely fai[l] to consider an important aspect of the problem.” Michigan, 576 U.S. at 752 (quoting State Farm, 463 U.S. at 43). Yet that is exactly what it did regarding female ownership (which it did not analyze) and the incentive auction (which it refused to consider). a. However irrational the Commission’s “analysis” of ownership data for people of color, the panel below correctly observed that the Commission did “not offer[] even that much as to the effect of its rules on female ownership.” App.40a. The Commission concluded that its rule changes “are not likely to harm … female ownership,” App.161a, based entirely on its assessment of data on ownership by people of color. See JA174-75 n.212. The FCC did not give any explanation of how this judgment about female ownership derived from data about something else. That silence is particularly troubling because the Commission’s own data show different patterns in ownership trends between women and people of color. See, e.g., CA3JA948-49; Data Summary, supra (ownership levels have not moved in lockstep for women and people of color). 40 The Commission’s only assessment of the likely effect of rule changes on female ownership was its unsupported conclusion that there would be none. That is no assessment at all; it is a wholesale failure to consider the entire problem. “[D]eference cannot fill the lack of an evidentiary foundation” for an agency’s conclusions. Bowen v. Am. Hosp. Ass’n, 476 U.S. 610, 643 (1986). The Government responds (Br. 37-38) that there was no 1990s-era data on female ownership, and that studying the effect of the cross-ownership restrictions, specifically, would have been impractical. But the Commission had other options. Studies in the record pointed to alternatives, see, e.g., CA3JA502 (showing that, all else equal, female radio-station ownership declines when market concentration increases), and comments urged the Commission to undertake studies of other “natural experiments” using the Commission’s own post-1990s Form 323 data that did cover women, see, e.g., CA3JA1076 (urging study of ownership before and after the Commission reinstated the failing station solicitation rule in 2008). To suggest that no alternatives were available is simply wrong. Purported difficulties in studying cross- ownership specifically, see SG Br. 42-43, are irrelevant. The Commission itself relied on local- ownership data when it found that repealing cross- ownership rules would not harm ownership diversity. App.120a, 139a. b. The Commission also failed to consider the effect of the incentive auction despite receiving comments that the auction was reducing ownership by women and people of color, and an express instruction 43 to have any meaningful impact on minority and female ownership levels.”). It plainly said the opposite for the local television, radio, and cross-ownership rules. Stripped of its contrived re-interpretation of the 2016 Order, the Reconsideration Order’s about-face on whether the existing ownership rules promote race- and gender-ownership diversity is wholly unexplained, indeed, unacknowledged. When an agency changes course, it “must at least ‘display awareness that it is changing position’ and ‘show that there are good reasons for the new policy.’” Encino Motorcars, LLC, 136 S. Ct. at 2126 (quoting FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 556 U.S. 502, 515 (2009)). The Commission knows how to do so, and has transparently explained changes in position on other aspects of the rules. E.g., App.67a-69a. But nothing explains how—with no change in the record—the 2016 finding that the rules promote ownership by women and people of color became an “unsubstantiated hope” within the space of a year. C. The Commission’s Decision Rested on an Arbitrary Assessment of the Past, Not a Reasoned Predictive Judgment. Judicial deference to difficult predictive judgments cannot salvage the Commission’s unreasoned conclusions. 1. The Government argues that agencies have substantial leeway to reach reasonable judgments and need not produce empirical evidence if it is difficult to do so. See Br. 22, 36 (citing Stilwell v. Office of Thrift Supervision, 569 F.3d 514, 519 (D.C. Cir. 2009)). But the Third Circuit held the agency only to the 44 requirement of a “reasoned explanation.” Stilwell, 569 F.3d at 519. It is uncontroverted, including by the Third Circuit, that the Commission could lawfully make a predictive judgment about the effect of relaxing its rules by relying on its experience and reasoned judgment. See App.40a; NCCB, 436 U.S. at 796-97. It was the Commission’s choice to rely on historical ownership data in making that prediction. And having chosen to rely on statistics in this way, the Commission did “not have free rein to use inaccurate data,” Dist. Hosp. Partners, L.P. v. Burwell, 786 F.3d 46, 56 (D.C. Cir. 2015) (emphasis omitted). The resulting (unreasoned) conclusion that past relaxations did not harm ownership diversity is a factual finding about a past event—not a prediction of how regulated parties will behave in the future. That retrospective analysis—which § 202(h) demands, as Industry Petitioners agree (Br. 32)—was the primary basis for any predictive judgment. The Government makes much of the proposition that when the Commission makes judgments “of a predictive nature,” “complete factual support … is not possible or required.” NCCB, 436 U.S. at 813-14. But no precedent provides agencies free rein to premise their predictions on irrational evaluations of past events. Because the Commission’s “no harm” projection is predicated on its irrational assessment of past data, it, too, is arbitrary. Especially when predictive judgments underpin drastic course reversals, they “must be based on some logic and evidence, not sheer speculation.” Sorenson Commc’ns Inc. v. FCC, 755 F.3d 702, 708 (D.C. Cir. 2014). 45 2. In an odd turn, the Government now claims (Br. 41) that the Third Circuit, not the Commission, “seriously overestimated” the probative force of the historical station count, because the market has changed since the 1990s. But it was the Commission that concluded the historical data was probative in the first place. See, e.g., App.161a. The Third Circuit merely explained that the conclusion drawn from that data was arbitrary. In its discussion of the newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership rule, the Reconsideration Order also relied on the 2014 Notice’s tentative conclusion that proposed modifications would not likely harm ownership diversity. App.117a; JA82; see also SG Br. 29. But that 2014 proposed rule was far less drastic than total repeal. And the 2016 Order repudiated that conclusion. See JA221; JA293. Nor does the purported support of two groups representing diverse owners let the agency off the hook. App.117a-18a; see also SG Br. 30. The few comments supporting relaxation of the newspaper/ broadcast cross-ownership rule (to the extent they even do), only underscore how barren the record was of support for repealing or relaxing the other rules without harming ownership diversity. For the radio/television cross-ownership rule, the Commission again cited the invalid station-count comparison, adding that the local radio rule would prevent “significant additional consolidation.” App.138a-39a. But the Commission nowhere denies the likelihood of some additional radio consolidation, which is particularly damaging to ownership diversity because—as even the Commission agrees—“broadcast 48 public interest, which includes ownership diversity. And commenters did submit extensive empirical analysis on the question, evidence that the Commission ignored. D. Nothing in § 202(h) Exempts the Commission from the Ordinary APA Requirement to Show Its Work. Effectively claiming that future reviews will be hampered by the Third Circuit’s application of basic administrative law principles, the Government seeks (Br. 24-27, 43-47) special deference to its § 202(h) decisions, arguing that the statute demands predictive judgments based on imperfect information and the short life cycle of any review mitigates the harmful effects of wrong decisions. Both rationales for straying from settled judicial review standards miss the mark. 1. The Commission’s conception of § 202(h) as predominantly requiring predictive judgments, and thereby mandating more deferential review, misunderstands the statutory inquiry. Section 202(h) requires the Commission to determine whether, “as the result of competition,” its rules remain useful in the public interest, and to repeal those that “no longer” are. These phrases focus the inquiry on the past and present. Any predictive element is premised on a reasoned analysis of past events—the statute provides no license to experiment and see what happens, as the Government argues. See Br. 46-47. The agency had (and has) many other plausible options to reasonably evaluate whether its ownership rules remain necessary in the public interest. See supra at 38-40. 49 Nor is the Government’s let’s-try-it-and-see explanation plausible: The Commission here did not claim this justification or dip a toe into the deregulatory waters; it jettisoned two rules entirely, substantially loosened a third, and undercut the last standing radio rule by adopting an incubator program that weakens it. That extra-statutory need-to- experiment rationale might arguably justify a relaxation or repeal of one rule (if grounded in rational findings), but the Commission deregulated broadcast- ownership wholesale. 2. Hope of future correction does not relieve the Commission of its statutory obligation to meet ordinary reasoned decision-making standards when assessing whether rules remain necessary in the public interest. A wrong call on public-interest harm (as here) cannot readily be undone even if rules are later restored. Beyond the practical difficulty of unscrambling the eggs once mergers take place, complete restoration is unlikely because of entrenched policies limiting divestiture. See NCCB, 436 U.S. at 811-12. And, as the 40% drop in minority ownership of full-power television stations following the 1990s relaxation shows, even if ownership diversity arguably recovers, it can take years. See CA3JA551; CA3JA568- 69 (Free Press study). Four years between reviews (or more, given the Commission’s history of delays) is far too late to put the genie back in the bottle. In urging more lenient scrutiny, the Government also argues (Br. 44-45) that the panel’s requirement of a reasoned explanation “with respect to a single public-interest factor” has frozen outdated ownership rules in place for decades and subjected broadcasters to harm. See also Industry Br. 8-9. 50 But any purported “freezing” of ownership rules is the Commission’s doing, not the Third Circuit’s. The Commission itself re-adopted most of its rules in 2008 and 2016. The Commission (until now) declined to repeal the newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership rule entirely, and the Commission took nearly ten years between this “quadrennial” review and the last one. See supra at 14-15; 17-19. In any event, asserting broadcaster harm from delay (much like the Commission’s analysis) ignores that the public-interest inquiry is multi-faceted. Petitioners repeatedly insist that Respondents have not contested the Commission’s analysis of competition. But that misses the point. The statutory charge is to regulate in the public interest, not the broadcasters’ competitive interest. Respondents have consistently argued that the rules are still necessary in the public interest writ large, and that harms to the public interest caused by repeal outweigh any benefit. Beyond that, the Reconsideration Order’s analysis of competition and localism is hardly universally accepted. Just a year before, on the same record, the Commission found that notwithstanding “broadband Internet and other technological advances,” “[t]raditional media outlets … are still of vital importance,” and the rules are necessary to “promote competition and a diversity of viewpoints in local markets.” JA103-04. Ultimately, the competition analysis was a contested and close policy call, with the new Commission majority reversing course on reconsideration to conclude that jettisoning the ownership rules would not harm competition. This about-face was maybe (at least arguably) reasonably 53 If a reasonable assessment of ownership diversity convinces the Commission that tighter ownership limits are needed, it would almost certainly likewise alter the Commission’s assessment of how narrowly to draw its eligibility criteria for an incubator program or other ownership limit waivers. Because the ownership rules and programs waiving those rules necessarily must work coherently together, the Third Circuit reasonably returned the entire regulatory scheme to the agency for it to decide based on a reasoned and transparent analysis how to use the tools at its disposal—ownership restrictions (including attribution rules), exceptions for “eligible entities,” and incubator programs—to best serve the public interest.16 C. Industry Petitioners object to the Third Circuit’s decision to retain jurisdiction over the case. Br. 49-51. The Government does not join in, perhaps because it has repeatedly agreed with decisions to return this case to the Third Circuit. See supra at 14, 20. Courts have discretion to retain jurisdiction over agency action on remand to expedite further review and foster judicial economy given familiarity with the issues. See, e.g., Nat’l Ass’n of Regulatory Util. Comm’rs v. U.S. Dep’t of Energy, 680 F.3d 819, 820 (D.C. Cir. 2012) (retaining jurisdiction to expedite review); Castañeda-Castillo v. Holder, 638 F.3d 354, 16 Petitioners also object (SG Br. 47 n.7; Industry Br. 47-48) to vacatur of the repeal of the Joint Sales Agreement (JSA) attribution rule for local television and the embedded markets rule for radio. But Industry Petitioners have previously argued that JSA rules effectively “amend the … ownership limits,” and the Third Circuit agreed. Prometheus III, 824 F.3d at 57. The embedded markets rule does the same for radio. 54 367 (1st Cir. 2011) (retaining jurisdiction over agency remand in case that had been “ping-ponging” for years). Retention of jurisdiction was not an abuse of discretion here, given the Commission’s own delays in completing the 2010/2014 Review and complying with prior remands, see Prometheus III, 824 F.3d at 48-51, and the panel’s deep knowledge of the issues.17 Petitioners have the full choice of venue for any petitions for review of new, distinct agency rulemakings. Intertwined issues have prompted transfer of new quadrennial reviews to the Third Circuit in the past—with the Commission’s blessing— in large part because the Commission has combined its remand decisions with its quadrennial reviews. Nothing in the Third Circuit’s decision here compels the Commission to do so, however, and Industry Petitioners submit no other reason why retention of jurisdiction is improper. D. Because the Commission has never purported to abandon ownership diversity as a public-interest goal within § 202(h) reviews, it was proper for the Third Circuit to state that the Commission must, on remand, evaluate the likely effect of its ownership rule changes on race and gender ownership. Direction to correct flawed analysis is an administrative commonplace when an agency arbitrarily assesses or ignores an important aspect of the problem before it. See, e.g., Dep’t of Homeland Sec. v. Regents of Univ. of Cal., 140 S. Ct. 1891, 1916 (2020) (“remand[ing] to 17 The Hobbs Administrative Orders Review Act, 28 U.S.C. § 2342(1), does not dictate otherwise. It is silent on a court’s authority to retain jurisdiction in any given case. 55 DHS so that it may consider the problem anew” when it “failed to consider [two] conspicuous issues”). This directive to show your work poses no Vermont Yankee problem. That case recognized that the APA authorizes a reviewing court to “remand an agency decision because of the inadequacy of the record.” Vermont Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 435 U.S. 519, 544 (1978). And the Third Circuit properly left the agency free “to develop the needed evidence” and determine “how its prior decision should be modified in light of such evidence.” Id. There was no unyielding order to the Commission to adduce new evidence; a better analysis would do. App.41a (noting the agency could engage in “new empirical research or an in-depth theoretical analysis”). And that analysis is possible on (and even included in) the existing record. See supra at 15-17; 38- 40. Nor does the mandate impair the Commission’s discretion to transparently re-weigh competing public- interest considerations (obviating the need for extensive analysis of ownership diversity, should the Commission decide to explicitly abandon the goal). It merely guarantees that so long as the Commission continues to profess a commitment to ownership diversity, it must reasonably implement that commitment. It has not done so. ADDENDUM TABLE OF CONTENTS 47 U.S.C. § 151 .......................................................... 1a 47 U.S.C. § 161 .......................................................... 2a 47 U.S.C. § 257(a)-(b) ................................................ 3a 47 U.S.C. § 303 note .................................................. 4a 47 U.S.C. § 309(i)-(j) .................................................. 7a 1a 47 U.S.C. § 151 Purposes of chapter; Federal Communications Commission created For the purpose of regulating interstate and foreign commerce in communication by wire and radio so as to make available, so far as possible, to all the people of the United States, without discrimination on the basis of race, color, religion, national origin, or sex, a rapid, efficient, Nation-wide, and world-wide wire and radio communication service with adequate facilities at reasonable charges, for the purpose of the national defense, for the purpose of promoting safety of life and property through the use of wire and radio communications, and for the purpose of securing a more effective execution of this policy by centralizing authority heretofore granted by law to several agencies and by granting additional authority with respect to interstate and foreign commerce in wire and radio communication, there is created a commission to be known as the “Federal Communications Commission”, which shall be constituted as hereinafter provided, and which shall execute and enforce the provisions of this chapter. 2a 47 U.S.C. § 161. Regulatory reform (a) Biennial review of regulations In every even-numbered year (beginning with 1998), the Commission-- (1) shall review all regulations issued under this chapter in effect at the time of the review that apply to the operations or activities of any provider of telecommunications service; and (2) shall determine whether any such regulation is no longer necessary in the public interest as the result of meaningful economic competition between providers of such service. (b) Effect of determination The Commission shall repeal or modify any regulation it determines to be no longer necessary in the public interest. 5a radio stations, not more than 4 of which are in the same service (AM or FM); and “(D) in a radio market with 14 or fewer commercial radio stations, a party may own, operate, or control up to 5 commercial radio stations, not more than 3 of which are in the same service (AM or FM), except that a party may not own, operate, or control more than 50 percent of the stations in such market. * * * * “(c) Television ownership limitations. “(1) National ownership limitations. The Commission shall modify its rules for multiple ownership set forth in section 73.3555 of its regulations (47 C.F.R. 73.3555)— “(A) by eliminating the restrictions on the number of television stations that a person or entity may directly or indirectly own, operate, or control, or have a cognizable interest in, nationwide; and “(B) by increasing the national audience reach limitation for television stations to 39 percent. “(2) Local ownership limitations. The Commission shall conduct a rulemaking proceeding to determine whether to retain, modify, or eliminate its limitations on the number of television stations that a person or entity may own, operate, or 6a control, or have a cognizable interest in, within the same television market. * * * * “(h) Further Commission review. The Commission shall review its rules adopted pursuant to this section and all of its ownership rules quadrennially as part of its regulatory reform review under section 11 of the Communications Act of 1934 [47 U.S.C. 161] and shall determine whether any of such rules are necessary in the public interest as the result of competition. The Commission shall repeal or modify any regulation it determines to be no longer in the public interest. This subsection does not apply to any rules relating to the 39 percent national audience reach limitation in subsection (c)(1)(B). * * * * 7a 47 U.S.C. § 309. Application for license * * * * (i) Random selection. (1) General authority. Except as provided in paragraph (5), if there is more than one application for any initial license or construction permit, then the Commission shall have the authority to grant such license or permit to a qualified applicant through the use of a system of random selection. * * * * (3) (A) The Commission shall establish rules and procedures to ensure that, in the administration of any system of random selection under this subsection used for granting licenses or construction permits for any media of mass communications, significant preferences will be granted to applicants or groups of applicants, the grant to which of the license or permit would increase the diversification of ownership of the media of mass communications. To further diversify the ownership of the media of mass communications, an additional significant preference shall be granted to any applicant controlled by a member or members of a minority group. * * * *
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved