Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Understanding Poverty Rates: A Look into Low Wages and Work Hours, Study notes of Economics

The relationship between low wages, poverty rates, and work hours. It discusses the challenges in measuring annual hours of work and the impact of part-time and full-time employment on poverty rates. The document also touches upon the importance of considering secondary workers and the role of minimum wages in addressing poverty.

Typology: Study notes

Pre 2010

Uploaded on 10/01/2009

koofers-user-jmu
koofers-user-jmu 🇺🇸

10 documents

1 / 6

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download Understanding Poverty Rates: A Look into Low Wages and Work Hours and more Study notes Economics in PDF only on Docsity! ECO 450G Notes - Spring 2003 Semester – February 11, 2003 Chapter 4 – The Working Poor I. Work Experience and Poverty II. Searching for Explanations III. Minimum Wage Jobs IV. Low Wages V. Why Wages are so Low VI. Summary VII. Does Prosperity Trickle Down? I. Work Experience and Poverty There are obviously a number of poor who are “subemployed” – having either part-time or part- year jobs, which provide insufficient income to lift the family out of poverty. Obviously, moving out of poverty depends on the intensity of work and the wage opportunities. Weeks of Work and Hours In principle, one could trace out poverty rates by annual hours of work. The CPS asks questions about the number of weeks employed in the last calendar year, and the usual hours worked per week (when employed). Unfortunately, annual hours of work in the CPS can only be approximated, because “usual” hours of work per week may refer to the median or mode hours of work (or something else), rather than the mean. For example, suppose that a person worked part-time (20 hours) for slightly more than one-half of the year, and full-time for slightly less than one-half of the year. Then “usual hours” could be 20 hours (the median and mode), 30 hours (the mean), or perhaps 40 hours if the person’s most recent job was full-time. The questionnaire for the 1998 CPS can be found at: http://www.census.gov/apsd/techdoc/cps/mar98/ques98.pdf The exact question reads: “In the weeks that you worked, how many hours did you usually work per week?” (See Question 41 of the survey). Obviously, the word “usually” can be interpreted in different ways, and it is not clear how this question accounts for second jobs / temporary jobs. Schiller’s Figure 4.1 shows that poverty rates decline rapidly, for both part-time and full-time workers as they work a greater portion of the year. Poverty rates are lowest for full-time, full- year workers. There are a number of issues with this table: 1) Poverty rates actually increase for part-time workers going from 1-13 weeks of work to 14-26 weeks. It is hard to know what to make of this increase – it may be possible that heads with 1-13 weeks of work are different in some way (e.g., family circumstances) than those with 14-26 weeks. This is purely speculation, however. Notice that at this level, full-time workers also have higher poverty rates than part-time workers. Again, it is not transparent why this should be so. 2) Poverty rates for those with zero weeks of work are not shown. 3) The work behavior is for the head of household, and does not account for family circumstances. Perhaps the most important family circumstance would be between married and single househlds. 4) Part-time is defined as 1-34 hours per week, full-time as 35-plus. Since a substantial fraction of full time jobs are centered at 40 hours per week, it is fairly clear how to translate “full-time” and “employed weeks” into annual hours. On the other hand, there is a great deal more dispersion in “part-time”hours. The Working Poor Less than half of the poor household heads (43%) have any work experience during the year. Of those working heads, however, two-thirds have a full time job (35-plus hours per week). Schiller claims “the presence of so many workers among the poor is a blatant contradiction to the accepted wisdom that ‘to get ahead, get a job’.” One should note from his pie chart in Figure 4.2, however, that only a small minority (14.2%) of poor household heads have a full-time, full- year job. It could certainly be the case that many of those poor households would exit poverty if they increased their work effort. How Much Work? There are different classifications of the “working poor.” Department of Labor definition – Persons who have devoted 27 weeks or more to working or looking for work and who lived in families with incomes below the official poverty threshold. Gorham and Harrison definition – All workers whose annualized earnings are too low to lift a family of four out of poverty. As Schiller mentions, both definitions have problems. More Measurement Problems 1) Usual hours per week – A person classified as “full-time” may occasionally experience “part- time” work. Around 10% of full-time, full-year workers actually had at least six weeks of part- time work. 2) Tips, commissions, bonuses – Schiller incorrectly claims that “The annual Census survey inquires about regular wages but neglects tips, commissions, and bonuses. These irregular forms of income may be particularly important for workers with low hourly pay (e.g., salespeople and food servers).” effects when better data is used to measure hiring. IV. Low Wages One wage earner in a family of four would need an $8/hour job to escape poverty. Table 4.3 in the text shows annual earnings of the head of poor families. Note that a surprisingly high number of full-time, full-year heads (12.7%) report earnings of less than $2,000, translating into an hourly wage rate of about $1/hour. These clearly suggest that there is measurement error in either earnings or annual hours. Moreover, if we divide earnings by full-time, full-year hours of work, about 41.1% of poor heads are apparently earning less than the minimum wage. This seems implausibly high. Table 4.4 shows the distribution of wage rates by age groups; nearly 25 million workers were paid less than $8/hour. Among low earners, many were able to escape poverty however. The most common way that low earners escaped poverty is by having a small family size, and other common ways included having other workers in the family, unearned income, and welfare benefits. Poor Jobs The reported occupations of poor heads of household are concentrated in a number of areas – the most common of which are “Other service workers,” “Craftspeople and precision production,” “Salesworkers,” and “Clerical workers.” V. Why are Wages so Low? Economics would suggest that wage rates are determined by supply and demand. There is ample supply of workers for unskilled jobs, hence wages remain low. Schiller argues that the demand side of the market is neglected in antipoverty discussions, and by doing so ignores tremendous potential for eliminating poverty. He says that “the distribution of wages and incomes is partly a reflection of collective social decisions regarding the merits of particular kinds of output. ... Had we decided instead to dredge more rivers, to build more houses, or to clear up our cities, the extent and nature of poverty might now be marked different.” Again, Schiller’s analysis assumes no behavioral responses. If unskilled occupations paid more, one could reasonably expect that skilled individuals would shift into them. For example, child- care workers and social workers are often paid very little – yet might be rewarding in a number of ways. One might expect that more skilled individuals would shift into occupations like those if they were more handsomely rewarded. VI. Summary Many people are poor despite relatively high attachments to the labor force – regardless of the measurement issues. VII. Does Prosperity Trickle Down Do the poor benefit from general economic growth or do they live in an isolated subeconomy? The trickle down perspective Asserts that people at the bottom of the economic hierarchy benefit from increased prosperity as higher income levels, because of multiplier effects. The dual labor market perspective Asserts that a variety of barriers, such as discrimination (either overt or in a statistical sense) or unions reduce the benefits from growth at the top of the income distribution.
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved