Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Sticky Wages, Efficiency Wages, and Unemployment: A Combinatorial Analysis, Study notes of Literature

Economic TheoryMicroeconomicsMacroeconomicsLabor Economics

A research paper that explores the relationship between sticky wages, efficiency wages, and unemployment. The author, C. Simon Fan from Lingnan University in Hong Kong, presents a model that suggests employed workers tend to supply more effort during economic downturns, which can partially mitigate the effects of negative demand shocks on output. The paper also discusses the implications of this model for labor markets and the relationship between wages, employment, and real output.

What you will learn

  • How does the combined analysis of sticky wages and efficiency wages impact workers' effort and unemployment?
  • How does the 'work-sharing' policy impact employment and real output according to the model?
  • What is the efficiency wage theory and how does it relate to unemployment?
  • How does the sticky wage theory explain involuntary unemployment?

Typology: Study notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 07/05/2022

lee_95
lee_95 🇦🇺

4.6

(59)

1K documents

1 / 26

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download Sticky Wages, Efficiency Wages, and Unemployment: A Combinatorial Analysis and more Study notes Literature in PDF only on Docsity! Sticky Wage, Efficiency Wage, and Keynesian Unemployment* C. Simon Fan+ Lingnan University, Hong Kong Abstract This paper provides a model of involuntary unemployment by combining the insights of the sticky wage theory and the efficiency wage theory. It implies that employed workers tend to supply more effort in response to economic downturns. Thus, a negative shock to an economy has intriguing impacts on the unemployment. The model also shows that a negative demand shock may have a relatively small effect on output since changes in work effort serve to partially mitigate the effects of the shock. Moreover, it yields some implications that complement the existing “work-sharing” literature. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Number: E24, J64 * Suggested Running Head: Sticky/ Efficiency Wage and Unemployment + Address for Correspondence: Department of Economics, Lingnan University, Tuen Mun, Hong Kong. E-mail: fansimon@ln.edu.hk. Telephone number: 852-2616-7206. Fax number: 852-2891-7940. I am grateful to an anonymous referee for constructive comments and suggestions. I also thank Ann Owen and Yue Ma for helpful comments and the seminar participants at Lingnan University for discussions. The remaining errors are my own 1 “Unemployment, like cancer, is a multifaceted phenomenon that comes in many forms.” (Summers, 1988: 388) 1. Introduction A fundamental assumption of traditional Keynesian economics is the rigidity of nominal wage rate (e.g. Romer, 2001). Due to the sticky wage rate, a reduction of labor demand in a recession will result in an increase in involuntary unemployment. In recent years, the studies of nominal wage rigidity have experienced resurgence in the research on business cycle fluctuations.1 Also, a major development of the “new” Keynesian economics is the efficiency wage theory. An important insight of the efficiency wage theory is that higher real wages and higher unemployment rates elicit more effort from workers and hence make them more productive.2 As the efficiency wage can be higher than the wage rate that equates labor demand and labor supply, this theory provides an explanation for the phenomena of persistent involuntary unemployment. This paper attempts to extend the existing literature by combining the insights of the sticky wage theory and the efficiency wage theory. First, based on the efficiency wage theory, firms choose the optimal wage rate that maximizes profits. Then, labor contracts are signed which specify the nominal wage. The contracts may be explicit formal agreements of the type specified in Fischer (1977) and Taylor (1980) or implicit informal agreements of the form described in Malcomson (1984). Next, this paper tries 4 whether a reduction of the working time of the employed can lead to an increase or decrease in employment.4 By considering that labor input includes both working hours and working intensity, the current paper extends this literature. For example, it suggests that the “work-sharing” scheme may not be effective in affecting wage and employment because reduced working hours may be offset by increased working intensity/effort. Further, the model implies that the “work-sharing” scheme will reduce real output even if it can increase employment. In what follows, Section 2 sets up the basic framework. Section 3 analyzes the impacts of a negative shock on workers’ efforts and involuntary unemployment. Section 4 explores other macroeconomic implications of the model. Section 5 summarizes the paper. The appendix discusses the empirical motivations of this paper. 2. The Basic Analytical Framework This section is completely based on the standard textbook version of the efficiency wage theory with slight modifications (see Chapter 9, Romer, 2001). There are a large number, N, of identical competitive firms. For simplicity, “N” is assumed to be fixed in the short run. The representative firm seeks to maximize its profits, which are: WLPQ −=π (2.1) where P is the price level, Q is the firm’s quantity of output, W is the nominal wage, L is the number of workers it hires. 5 A firm’s output depends on both the number of workers it employs and their effort. Thus the representative firm’s output is ( ) ( ) ( ) 0,0, <•′′>•′= FFeLFQ (2.2) where e denotes workers’ effort. The efficiency wage theory posits that workers’ effort increases with the real wage rate and the unemployment rate (e.g. Solow, 1979; Summers, 1988). Namely, 0,0,, 21 >>     = eeu P Wee (2.3) where u denotes the unemployment rate. There are L identical workers, each of whom supplies one unit of labor inelastically. Also, we only consider the case that there are unemployed workers so that the firms can choose the wage freely. Based on the above description, the problem facing the representative firm is WLLu P WePF WL −            , , max , (2.4) Since there are a large number of firms, each individual firm regards “u ” as given. Then, the first order conditions for L and W are 0,, , =−                 ′= ∂ ∂ Wu P WeLu P WeFP L π (2.5) 0,, , 1 =−                 ′= ∂ ∂ Lu P WeLu P WeF W π (2.6) 6 Since firms are identical, each firm chooses the same values of W and L. Total labor demand is therefore NL . To guarantee an interior solution, we assume LNL < . In this case, the number of unemployed workers is NLL − So, L NLLu − = (2.7) Plugging (2.7) into (2.5) and (2.6), we can get a firm’s optimal choice of W and L , which are denoted by *W and *L , respectively. 3. Sticky Wage, Efficiency Wage, and Unemployment In this section, I will examine the combined implications of the sticky wage theory and the efficiency wage theory on workers’ effort and unemployment in an economic downturn. First, based on the efficiency wage theory discussed in the last section, firms choose the optimal wage rate that maximizes profits. Then, labor contracts are signed which specify the nominal wage at the level of *W . Next, I assume that after labor contracts are signed, a completely unexpected negative shock occurs to the economy. I assume that the economy here is a small open economy so that firms in this economy take the price of the output, P, as given. Hence, the negative shock to the economy here can be simply modeled as a fall of the price of output, P.5 As the negative shock is completely unexpected, the predetermined efficiency wage, *W , may no longer maximize firms’ profit in the new macroeconomic environment. However, as the nominal wage rate is fixed or sticky in the short run, firms can only 9 To obtain the expression of e L ∂ ∂ , I totally differentiate (3.2) with respect to L and e and rearrange, then I get Fe FeLF e L ′′ ′′+′ −= ∂ ∂ 2 (3.7) Note that the denominator of (3.7) is negative since 0<′′F . Thus, if ( )0<>′′+′ FeLF , we have ( )0<> ∂ ∂ e L The intuition of the above result is as follows. On one hand, as workers supply more effort, ceteris paribus, the effective labor supply (i.e. eL ) will increase. As the effective labor supply increases, according to the law of diminishing returns, firms will tend to lay off more workers. On the other hand, as workers’ effort increases, the value of each worker to the firm increases, which implies that firms, will tend to retain/hire more workers. From (3.7), we can see that the net effect will depend on the curvature of the production function. If the marginal product of labor decreases little with effective labor supply, eL , the absolute value of F ′′ will be small. In this case, firms will choose to retain more workers in response to an increase of workers’ effort. However, if the production function exhibits strong diminishing returns, then firms will choose to lay off more workers as e increases. Now, to derive the expression of dP dL , I rearrange (3.4) as follows, dP dL L u u e e L dP de e L P L dP dL ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ + ∂ ∂ + ∂ ∂ = namely 10 dP de e L P L L u u e e L dP dL ∂ ∂ + ∂ ∂ =    ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ −1 (3.8) Plugging (3.3), (3.5), (3.6) and (3.7) into (3.8) and rearranging, I get ( )[ ] ( )[ ]FNeFLNeeeLP FLeeWFePeWL L Ne Fe FeLF P eW Fe FeLF FeP F L u u e e L P e e L P L dP dL ′−′′− ′′+′− =                  − ′′ ′′+′ −−               − ′′ ′′+′ − ′′ ′ −=     ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ −    ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ + ∂ ∂ = 22 22 1 * 1 * 2 22 1 * 2 1/ 1/ (3.9) (3.9) and (3.4) imply that there is an intriguing relationship between employment and the change of economic environment when we take workers’ endogenous effort into account. Comparing (3.3) and (3.4), we can see that if the prediction of unemployment is based on the sticky wage theory but it ignores the implications of the efficiency wage theory, then the impact of the negative shock on unemployment will be either overestimated or underestimated. The impact of a negative demand shock on increasing unemployment will be overstated if 0> ∂ ∂ − e L or 0>′′+′ FeLF ; it will be understated 0< ∂ ∂ − e L or 0<′′+′ FeLF . Moreover, comparing (3.3) with (3.4) and noting (3.7), (3.5), (3.6) and (3.9), we can see that the magnitude of this overestimation or underestimation is the absolute value of the following item 11 ( )[ ] ( )[ ] ( ) ( )[ ] ( )[ ]{ } ( )[ ] ( ) ( )[ ] ( )[ ]FeLLNeeFNePFe FePNeFeLLNeeLeeWFeLF FNeFLNeeeLPFe FLeeWFePeWNeFNeFLNeeeLeWFeLF FNeFLNeeeLP FLeeWFePeWL L Ne P eW Fe FeLF dP dL L u u e P e e L ′′−+′′′ ′−′′+−′′+′ = ′−′′−′′ ′′+′−+′−′′−′′+′ =       ′−′′− ′′+′− −− ′′ ′′+′ −=       ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ + ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ 2 22 22 2 2 21 * 2 2 222 1 * 1 * 222 2 1 * 22 22 1 * 1 * 2 2 1 * 2 Thus, as firms may either retain or lay off more workers in response to the increase of workers’ effort, the amount of increased unemployment in a recession predicted by the combined insights of both the efficiency wage theory and the sticky wage theory can be significantly different from that predicted by the sticky wage theory alone. 4. Effort, Real Output, and Policy Implications In this section, I first analyze the impact of endogenous effort on real output. From (2.2), namely ( )eLFQ = , we know that the real output is determined by the effective labor supply (i.e. eL ). As in the last section, the change of macroeconomic environment is again modeled as the change of “ P ”. Then, the relationship between effective labor supply and the change of macroeconomic environment is ( ) dP dLe dP deL dP eLd += (4.1) As 0< dP de , dP dLe dP deL + can be much less than dP dLe . In other words, the change of effective labor supply due to a negative shock can be much smaller than what is 14 ( ) ( ) 0 2 > ′′ ′ −= ′′ ′′+′ −= += Fe F Fe FeLFeL de LdeL de eLd “ ( ) 0> de eLd ” means that a reduction in hours or/and efforts per worker will result in a decrease in the total effective labor supply. Thus, no matter whether the “work-sharing” scheme succeeds in increasing employment or not, it will result in a decrease in real output. 5. Summary Both the sticky wage theory and the efficiency wage theory are cornerstone theories of involuntary unemployment in macroeconomics. However, in the existing literature, to my best knowledge no attempt has been made to explore the combined implications of these two theories. This paper intends to help fill this gap. The basic structure of the model is as follows. First, based on the efficiency wage theory, firms choose the optimal wage rate that maximizes profits. Then, labor contracts are signed which specify the nominal wage. Next, I try to answer the question: what will happen if an unexpected negative shock occurs to an economy after labor contracts are signed? The model implies that in economic downturns, while few people work, those who are employed tend to work harder. Moreover, it suggests that firms’ employment decisions are related to workers’ effort in a rather complex way. On one hand, as effective labor supply increases with workers’ effort, the law of diminishing returns 15 implies that firms will tend to lay off more workers. On the other hand, as workers’ effort increases, the value of each worker to the firm increases, which implies that firms will tend to retain more workers. The net effect depends on the property of the production function. Thus, it suggests that a negative shock to an economy has intriguing impacts on the unemployment. In other words, the amount of increased unemployment in a recession can be significantly different from the prediction of a model in which workers’ endogenous efforts are not taken into account. The model also generates other macroeconomic and policy implications. It shows that a negative demand shock may have a relatively small effect on output since changes in work effort serve to partially mitigate the effects of the shock. Also, it suggests that as labor input includes both working hours and working intensity, the “work-sharing” scheme may not be effective in affecting wage and employment if reduced working hours are offset by increased work effort. Further, it implies that the “work-sharing” scheme will reduce real output even if it can increase employment. 16 6.Appendix: Empirical Motivations This paper is motivated by the observations in Hong Kong for the past few years. From late 1997 to 2004, the Hong Kong economy had generally been in a state of economic downturn. In particular, from October 1998 to June 2004, Hong Kong consumer prices had fallen for 66 straight months and its unemployment rate had risen drastically.7 Meanwhile, as Hong Kong had enjoyed very rapid economic growths for several decades before 1997, the prolonged recession was largely unexpected. Also, it should be noted that unions have never had much power or influence in Hong Kong. So, Hong Kong is an ideal place to study the implications of the standard efficiency wage theories. Why is the unemployment rate in Hong Kong so high? Firstly, a general consensus is that the nominal wage rate in Hong Kong has been sticky, which is related to the currency peg between Hong Kong dollar and American dollar. In fact, for those years, the average nominal wage rate in Hong Kong has experienced slight increases despite the continuous deflations and increasing unemployment.8 Secondly, there are some concerns that the unemployment problem in Hong Kong was worsened by the increasing trend that more and more workers frequently and even voluntarily worked overtime without any extra pay.9 In September 2001, the Democratic Alliance for the Betterment of Hong Kong, one of Hong Kong’s political parties, conducted a survey on the working hours of 655 19 Answers percentage of the respondents Yes 15.9% No 84.1% The above survey results illustrate that in economic downturns, workers usually work overtime with little or no extra compensation. Meanwhile, consistent with the implication of the sticky wage theory, few workers are willing to accept a pay cut even if they are overloaded and have to work overtime. Finally, from the Quarterly Report on the General Household Survey in Hong Kong, I find the median hours of work in Hong Kong, which is complementary to the above empirical evidence and is presented in the following table. Table 1 is about here From 1995 to 1997, Hong Kong economy was in a boom; from 1998 to 2000, it was in a recession. A simple comparison reveals that in each of the four quarters, the median hours of work in Hong Kong is higher in the period between 1998 and 2000 than the period between 1995 and 1997. Moreover, a t-statistic test demonstrates that the null hypothesis that the difference between the average hours in these two periods are the same can be rejected at the 1 percent significance level. Thus, this piece of evidence shows that a typical worker worked for longer hours during recessions than during booms in Hong Kong. 20 Table 1 The median hours of work in Hong Kong (hours per week) Year first quarter Second quarter thrird quarter fourth quarter 1995 44 44 45 45 1996 45 45 48 45 1997 44 45 45 45 1998 45 45 45 45 1999 45 45 48 48 2000 47 48 48 48 21 References Akerlof, G. A. (1982) ‘Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 97, 543-69. Bils, M. and Y. Chang (2003) ‘Welfare Costs of Sticky Wages When Effort Can Respond,’ Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 310-30. Calmfors, L. and M. Hoel (1989) ‘Work Sharing, Employment and Shiftwork,’Oxford Economic Papers 41, 758-73. Fischer, S. (1977) ‘Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule,’ Journal of Political Economy 85, 191-205. Hoel, M. and B. Vale (1986) ‘Effects on Unemployment of Reduced Working Time in an Economy Where Firms Set Wages,’ European Economic Review, 30, 1097-104. Hong Kong Monthly Digest, Census and Statistics Department, the Government of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, various issues. Hunt, J. (1998) ‘Hours Reductions as Work-Sharing,’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 339-69. 24 Footnotes 1 See, for example, the literature review in Bils and Chang (2003). 2 For example, see Solow (1979), Akerlof (1982), Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984), Summers (1988), and Weiss (1990). 3 In the model, I adopt the assumption of small open economy so that the output of the economy does not affect its price level. But if I relax this assumption, then an increase in output will reduce the price level, which will further reduce employment. 4 In many western countries, “work-sharing” schemes have been proposed as a policy instrument to reduce unemployment. This policy proposal is based on the widespread popular belief that a reduction in hours per worker will spread the available work around and hence increase employment. However, rigorous economic analyses indicate that “work-sharing” schemes often lead to rather complicated outcomes. For example, see Calmfors and Hoel (1989) and Hoel and Vale (1986) for some theoretical analyses, Hunt (1999) for some empirical investigations, and Hunt (1998) for a comprehensive survey of the “work-sharing” literature. 5 Note that the assumption of small open economy implies that prices are not sticky (e.g. Phelps, 1990). This assumption allows us to readily apply the existing theories of efficiency wage, which have not incorporated sticky price. If sticky price were to be considered, we then could extend the existing efficiency wage theories by 25 assuming that workers’ effort is a decreasing function of firms’ realized profits, which would lead to qualitatively the same results as those obtained in this paper. 6 Specifically, Hunt (1999) finds that when the standard hours in some industries in Germany were reduced by one hour due to the implementation of the “work-sharing” scheme, straight-time real hourly wages rose between 2 and 2.4 percent relative to wages in industries with no reduction in standard hours. As a one-hour fall from forty (standard) hours is equivalent to 2.5 percent, Hunt (1999) infers that workers were almost fully compensated pecuniarily. 7 See Hong Kong Monthly Digest. For example, the unemployment rate in Hong Kong was only 2.2 percent in 1997. But it surged to 7.8 percent in the first quarter of 2003. 8 See Hong Kong Monthly Digest. 9 For example, see “Fearful staffs work longer hours for no reward,” South China Morning Post (Hong Kong’s leading English newspaper), October 29, 2001. 10 See http://www.dab.org.hk/ (in Chinese). 11 It should be noted that in Hong Kong, employees are usually required to work on Saturday mornings so that the standard working days per week are five and half days.
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved