Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Iron Triangles: The Alignment of Interests in Public Policy Making, Study notes of Political Science

The Iron Triangle is a concept used to describe the alignment of interests and actions among three key actors in US public policy making: regulated industries or special interests, oversight committees in the legislature, and regulatory agencies or bureaucracies. how this alignment leads to regulatory decisions and policies that protect and promote the regulated industry, using the military-industrial complex as an example.

Typology: Study notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 03/31/2022

arold
arold 🇺🇸

4.7

(23)

126 documents

1 / 11

Toggle sidebar

Related documents


Partial preview of the text

Download Iron Triangles: The Alignment of Interests in Public Policy Making and more Study notes Political Science in PDF only on Docsity! Iron Triangles The term iron triangle has been used both by scholars and by muckraking popular writers to refer to the alignment of interests and actions among three key actors in public policy making in the United States: regulated industry or other special interests, the oversight committees in the legislature, and the regulatory agency or other bureaucracy. The typical outcome of this alignment is the production of both specific regulatory decisions and regulatory policies, including the regulations themselves, that tend to protect and promote the regulated industry. For example, in recent years, critics of the U.S. Food and Drug Administration have argued that pharmaceutical companies, with the support of Congress, have had undue influence in the decisions of the FDA, resulting in the marketing of drugs whose sometimes dangerous side- effects have not been tracked by the FDA or reported in a timely way by the companies. Sometimes the role of the regulatory agency is played by a public bureaucracy that has the ability to make decisions and/or resource allocations that are important to the industry. For example, the so-called military-industrial complex may be seen as an iron triangle among oversight committees in Congress, the Defense Department or particular branches of the military, and components of the defense industry. The term “military-industrial complex” was introduced in President Dwight Eisenhower’s Farewell Radio and Television Address to the American People on January 17, 1961. The speech was written by the political scientist Malcolm Moos. In the speech, Eisenhower warned that “In the councils of government, we must guard against the acquisition of unwarranted influence, whether sought or unsought, by the military-industrial complex. The potential for the disastrous rise of misplaced power exists and will persist.” Concern over the ill effects of the undue influence of private power was not new at the time of Eisenhower’s speech. This theme was common, for example, in Populist complaints in the nineteenth century, New Deal era criticisms of business, and the work of critical economists 2 and political scientists of the mid-twentieth century such as Horace Gray and Grant McConnell. Political scientists of that era, such as Merle Fainsod, Samuel Huntington, and Marver Bernstein, and, later, scholars such as Edwin Epstein, began to develop models linking the efforts of interest groups with the institutional structures in government that they sought to influence. Bernstein’s life cycle model is perhaps the best known. In it he argued that a regulatory agency follows a path of maturation, from aggressive regulation supported by the activist interest groups instrumental in the agency’s creation as a response to a social or economic problem, to an old age in which those groups no longer provide active support, and are replaced by the regulated industry. Over time, via repeated interactions in which the agency adjusts to the positive and negative pressures coming from the industry, the industry “captures” the regulatory process. Congress either gives little attention to the agency, or provides oversight that responds to the industry’s interests. Core Logic of the Iron Triangle The classic iron triangle is structured by the incentives that flow among its actors, as well as the opportunities provided by the institutions that populate the system. The same basic logic applies at any level of government, with appropriate adaptations of the argument. The core logic is described by Roger Noll and by Barry Mitnick, among others: The regulated industry is a significant economic actor in the constituencies of a set of legislators. Because the legislators desire to be reelected, and because they need the votes of constituents as well as funds to pay campaign expenses, they are sensitive to the requests of the industry. The industry can influence votes via its own employees and the dependence of the constituency on the economic success of the industry. In addition, either via its political action committee(s), or via allies, the industry can steer important resources to the elected politicians to aid in their campaigns. As a service to their district, and to promote their reelection, legislators seek to serve on committees of oversight that 5 Appointments to the top positions in the agencies are often determined by Presidential staff members (or, at other levels of government, by the staffs of the chief executive at that level); the President may not even meet the appointees. There is little public attention to the appointments, though the industry pays close attention and seeks to influence appointments. Usually, regulatory appointments are people who are at least not hostile to the industry, and for whom confirmation by the U.S. Senate is likely because legislators perceive that their constituencies will take no issue with the appointments. Legislators from districts/states where the industry is important are likely to put holds on nominations of prospective regulators opposed by industry in their constituencies. Thus, new top regulators are usually not committed to regulating against the fundamental interests of the industry they regulate. Finally, after making a personal investment in knowledge of the industry and its areas of professional expertise, regulators look for ways to cash in this knowledge and expertise once they leave the agency. The data show that top regulators, such as independent regulatory commissioners, and top administrators in single-headed bodies, do not on average stay their entire terms of appointment, nor do they even stay for an entire Presidential administration, if the setting is the U.S. Government. Thus, these regulators are frequently looking for their next job. The one place that is sure to have an interest in employing them, as long as they have not acquired a reputation for poor personal performance as a result of adverse public hearings, is the regulated industry. The regulated industry will even hire regulators who have been more aggressive in dealing with them, because of their expertise both in the industry and in the conduct of such regulation. In their classic 1970 muckraking study of the Interstate Commerce Commission, Robert Fellmeth and associates found that nine of the last eleven commissioners to have left the Commission at the time of the study had gone to work in the regulated industry or as lawyers 6 representing it. The other two commissioners simply retired. The traffic between government and the private sector and back again has even acquired the name “the revolving door.” It is not uncommon for all three actors in the triangle to take part in this, with top Congressional staff members, often attorneys, appointed to top regulatory positions as a reward for service to Congressional leaders, and to see them later rotate out to industry or to Washington law and lobbying firms that represent the industry. Often, regulators have held other jobs in government, and rotate to the regulatory body from or to a government job. Of the five members of the Federal Communications Commission in 2006, three were attorneys; two were former Congressional staff members; one was an industry lobbyist whose duties involved advocacy to Congress; four of the five had had jobs elsewhere in government before their appointments to the FCC, and the fifth had extensive experience in politics. Especially in past decades, the most common profession of a top Federal regulator was the law. This is a highly fungible profession, of course, but what it allows regulators to do is to move to Washington law firms or, sometimes, lobbying firms, after their service, and provide legal services to the industry they lately regulated. Conflict-of-interest laws are not difficult to end run in this regard. As long as the former regulator is not the attorney of record in representations before the agency, s/he can still provide consulting services to industry clients during the period of exclusion under these laws, and to his or her own law firm colleagues at any time. Having relied on the industry for information, received respect and prestige from the industry, gotten to know people in the industry as reasonable, credible folks, and seeing the opportunity of future employment in or dealing with the industry, regulators in this iron triangle find that, over time, their decisions as regulators tend to favor the industry. Thus, going around the triangle, we end up with legislators who take actions in the industry’s interests, as well as regulators who do the same. The industry gets what benefits it. 7 The structure of the triangle is remarkably stable, as long as the incentives stay the same, and no new actors enter to confuse the flow of such incentives. This rational choice model of the iron triangle assumes that regulators are often self- interested, or become so after being exposed to the incentive system in which they are embedded. Yet the model itself is overly simplistic. It is not hard to find cases of regulators, both historical and of more recent service, who viewed their roles as being stewards for the public interest, and/or of arbitrators of how the public interest should be pursued in the area being regulated. In addition, regulators who are civil servants, i.e., below the appointed levels, are often highly professional in orientation, especially in areas requiring technical expertise. They see their roles more as implementers and problem-solvers, rather than as de facto servants of the industry. In some historical contexts, belief in the desirability of a regulation that in practice protected the industry has been joined with dedicated service to the public. One example is Joseph Eastman, the long-time chairman of the Interstate Commerce Commission in the 1920s and 1930s. For him, any suggestion that his selfless dedication to the goals of transportation regulation represented protection of the modes in that industry (railroad, trucks, barges) against competition with one another – a conclusion reached by modern economists -- would have seemed insulting. Yet one cannot dispute that iron triangles were and are real, and are actively maintained and defended by the industry, political, and bureaucratic actors who run them. Iron triangles were very common in U.S. regulation before the last decades of the 20 th century, and remain active in a number of regulated areas today. For example, those in agriculture, such as navel oranges, are particularly protective of the industry. Beginning in the early 1970s, however, the public interest movement began to supply counter pressures that often cracked and even rusted the triangles away completely in some issue 10 Epstein, Edwin M. (1969). The corporation in American politics. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Heclo, Hugh. (1978). Issue networks and the executive establishment. In Anthony King (Ed.), The new American political system. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute. Krasnow, Erwin G.; Longley, Lawrence D.; & Terry, Herbert A. (1982). The politics of broadcast regulation. 3 rd Ed. New York: St. Martin’s Press. McConnell, Grant. (1966). Private power and American democracy. New York: Vintage Books, Alfred A. Knopf. Mitnick, Barry M. (1980). The political economy of regulation: Creating, designing, and removing regulatory forms. New York: Columbia University Press. Mitnick, Barry M. (1991). An incentive systems model of the regulatory environment. In Melvin J. Dubnick & Alan R. Gitelson (Eds.), Public policy and economic institutions, volume 10 in Public policy studies: A multi-volume treatise, Stuart S. Nagel (Ed.). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press (pp. 147-204). Noll, Roger G. (1971). Reforming regulation: An evaluation of the Ash Council proposals. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Quirk, Paul J. (1981). Industry influence in federal regulatory agencies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. IRON TRIANGLES & Jelly Hexagons Congress Committees Courts note Regulatory Industry <q_—_—_$#_———_————_+ Agency Citizen Groups A desqiption of the relationships within the tiangle, as well as the relationships among the six actors in the policy subgovemment-- the “jelly hexagon" -- appears in the entry for Iron Triangles. 11
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved