Docsity
Docsity

Prepara tus exámenes
Prepara tus exámenes

Prepara tus exámenes y mejora tus resultados gracias a la gran cantidad de recursos disponibles en Docsity


Consigue puntos base para descargar
Consigue puntos base para descargar

Gana puntos ayudando a otros estudiantes o consíguelos activando un Plan Premium


Orientación Universidad
Orientación Universidad

Understanding Market Mechanisms: Price Discrimination, Externalities, & Info Asymmetry, Apuntes de Economía

Market FailuresMarket MechanismsMacroeconomicsMicroeconomicsPrice Theory

The concept of markets and how they function effectively in a free economy. It discusses strategies like price discrimination, the role of scarcity, and the impact of externalities and private information on market performance. The document also touches upon the importance of fairness and the role of taxes and subsidies in balancing market excesses. It uses the examples of health care and insurance markets to illustrate market failures and potential solutions.

Qué aprenderás

  • How does price discrimination increase profits in imperfect markets?
  • What role does scarcity play in market mechanisms?
  • How can insurance companies reduce moral hazard?
  • What is the lemons problem and how does it impact markets?
  • How do externalities affect market performance?

Tipo: Apuntes

2018/2019

Subido el 24/06/2019

julio-h
julio-h 🇪🇸

4 documentos

1 / 12

Toggle sidebar

Documentos relacionados


Vista previa parcial del texto

¡Descarga Understanding Market Mechanisms: Price Discrimination, Externalities, & Info Asymmetry y más Apuntes en PDF de Economía solo en Docsity! The Undercover Economist By Tim Harford, Little Brown, 2006 What makes markets work? What makes something valuable? What is the basis for bargaining power? Why do poor countries struggle to develop? What is the impact of trade on the environment? Using the basic principles of economics, the author analyses various problems of day-to-day life. Daily life is full of puzzles. But many of us do not even realize them. This book helps us to understand these puzzles and what lies behind them. The importance of scarcity When a deal is being done between somebody who has something unique and someone who has something which can be replaced, the profits are likely to be cornered by the person with the unique resource. When relative scarcity shifts, the bargaining power of the people involved in the deal, also shifts. Some things are scarce because of natural factors. Others are scarce because of man made factors – legislation, regulation or foul play. For any company, grabbing or developing unique resources is really the only way of generating profits on a sustainable basis in the long run. These resources could be physical or intangible assets or some unique competencies. In the real world, people and organizations try to create scarcity by erecting barriers to entry in many ways. The purpose of a trade union is to prevent workers from competing with each other for jobs, thereby driving down wages and worsening working conditions. Professional bodies like doctors, actuaries, accountants and lawyers try to maintain high wages through long qualification periods. Some professional bodies give their approval to only a certain number of candidates per year. The CFA (USA) and CA (India) certification are good examples. Price Discrimination We learn in Economics that price discrimination is a good strategy to increase profits in imperfect markets. There are different ways of doing this. The first is to evaluate customers as individuals and charge according to how much each is willing to pay. This approach requires skill and effort. Where technology allows, as indeed the Internet does, firms with scarcity power can use highly sophisticated methods to target customers. The group target strategy is to offer different prices to members of distinct groups. This strategy seems more popular as people in groups who pay more are usually people who can afford more. People who can afford more are usually people who care less about price. But this is only a coincidence. Companies are targeting the people who are willing to pay more, not those who can afford to do so. The cleverest way to get better prices is to persuade customers into confessing that they are not sensitive to price. To achieve this, the company might offer products in different versions – size, features, location, etc. 2 No company has power to indulge in price discrimination unless it has scarcity. Sometimes, scarcity results because of the customers’ own laziness. Customers do not shop around sufficiently. Companies, on their part, should be careful about leaks in their marketing programs. Price sensitive customers may stay away from expensive products. But price insensitive customers may also stay away from them. Another risk is that customers who are being offered a discount may buy the product and resell it at a profit to customers who are being charged the higher price. The market mechanism In a free market, people do not buy things that are worth less to them than the asking price. And people do not sell things that are worth more to them than the asking price. Nobody is forcing them to. Most transactions that happen in a free market improve efficiency because they make both parties better off and don’t harm anyone else. In a perfectly competitive market, the price of coffee would equal the marginal cost of coffee. If the price were lower, firms would go out of business, until it arose. If the price were higher, new firms would enter or old firms would expand their output until it fell. A perfect market ensures that:  Companies are making things the right way  Companies are making the right things  Things are being made in the right proportions  Thinks are going to the right people. In short, there is nothing more efficient than a perfectly competitive market. A non market process may be desirable in a police service or a school system. But in general, non market systems do not adequately capture, information about wants, needs, desires, inconveniences and costs. Sometimes this loss of information is a worthwhile sacrifice for gains in equality or stability, but often, it can lead to waste and confusion the economy and society. There is no such confusion in a well functioning market because the price signals what people value and what they do not. When economists say the economy is inefficient, they mean that there is a way to make somebody better off without harming anybody else. The perfectly competitive market is perfectly efficient. But efficiency is not enough to ensure a fair society or even a society in which we want to live. Harford explains later on how the market mechanism can be supplemented by other governmental interventions to ensure equity. Taxes Taxes are inefficient because they distort the information carried by prices in perfectly competitive, efficient markets. Price no longer equals cost. So cost no longer equals value. We face a dilemma. What we need is a way to make our economy both efficient and fair. Nobel Prize winning Economist Kenneth Arrow proved that not only are all 5 incomplete insurance, in the form of an excess. Another way insurance companies can fight moral hazard is by gaining access to the inside information, such as smoking, existing ailments, etc. Keyhole surgery techniques allow surgeons to operate without making large incisions, minimising the risk of complications and side effects. Economists often advocate a similar strategy when trying to fix a policy problem, i.e., target the problem as closely as possible. Take the case of healthcare. Keyhole economics would first identify the specific market failures, which fall into three categories: scarcity power, externalities and imperfect information, plus the issue of fairness. Scarcity power is a potential problem, but for most treatments not a significant one. This diagnosis suggests a two-part keyhole treatment. The first part is to ensure the widespread availability of information: it should be easy to get a second opinion, to call a help-line, or to get information from libraries, clinics, the internet, even supermarkets. The second part is to give patients an opportunity to use this information. In a privatized, insurance-based system, the insurance company tends to make a lot of choices; in a government provided system, the government makes the choices. In a market-based system without insurance, the patient makes the choices. This is much better but the problem is that the patient also has to pay for unpredictable and potentially catastrophic health-care costs. How can we give patients choice and responsibility without putting an unbearable burden on them? The best system would compel patients to pay for many of the costs, thus providing an incentive to inform themselves and to make choices that are both in their interests and reasonably cost-effective but which leaves the most severe costs to the government or insurance. This might work, because most medical bills are not catastrophic and so do not need insurance. Such a system would give maximum responsibility and choice to patients, therefore requiring them to spend their own money rather than that of governments or insurers. But it would make sure that nobody faced catastrophic medical bills and ensure that even the poor had enough money to buy medical care. Markets work because our choice as consumers between competing producers gives them both the right incentives and the right information to produce the right amount of exactly what we want. And scarcity power, externalities and inside information can each ruin the way markets do this. In the case of health care, the market works poorly because while we want the reassurance of knowing we can afford expensive medical bills, inside information eats 6 away at the insurance by driving away low-risk customers and forcing premiums to rise. Private companies have developed ways to get around the problem, but they are expensive and bureaucratic. Singapore’s government tackled the problem head on, by using forced saving and catastrophe insurance to make sure costs were manageable but allowing patients sufficient freedom to exercise their choice. Rational Insanity Perfectly informed investors produce a random market, but a random market doesn’t reward anybody for becoming perfectly informed. It wouldn’t be worth anybody’s while to invest time and effort to analyse the market or uncover new information, if everybody else was doing the same. On the other hand, a market full of unexploited opportunities would offer big profits to any investor willing to research them, which would then lead to fewer unexploited opportunities. Somewhere in the middle is a balancing point: a nearly random market with enough quirks to reward the informed investors who keep it nearly random. We should not assume that an economic revolution will automatically lead to a rise in share prices. Share prices should rise only if there’s good reason to think that future profits will be high. As we know, profits derive from scarcity; for instance, ownership of scarce land (protected by legal title), a scarce brand (protected by trademark) or an organization with unique capabilities (protected by nothing more than the fact that most effective organizations are hard to copy). So share prices should rise only if economic transformation increases the degree to which organizations control scarce resources. There might be a link between economic transformation and the control of scarcity. Some companies will gain; others will lose. But there seems to be no clear link between economic transformation and high profits for the average company. In fact, the reverse is often true: economic transformation destroys the profitability of old firms (by replacing or duplicating their scarce assets), while the new firms that replace them often face a high failure rate and very large costs of building their businesses. The advantages are enjoyed by workers who are paid higher wages on average and by customers who pay lower prices or get new and better good and services. The economy will never change so much that companies with no scarcity power become highly profitable. The lessons for making stock market investment are clear enough. All stock prices incorporate tremendous expert knowledge. If we plan to try to make serious money, we better have a clear idea of what we think we know, and what market insiders are ignoring. Also long-lasting profitability for a company comes from having some capability that others cannot match: like a powerful brand in a conservative market. Why Poor Countries are Poor Poor countries should have been catching up with rich ones for the past century or so. Logically, the further behind they are, the faster the catch-up should be. Poorer 7 countries should catch up quickly because in a country which has very little in the way of infrastructure or education, new investments should generate quick and attractive returns. Rich countries don’t gain much from further investment. This is called ‘diminishing returns’. When we look at countries like Taiwan, South Korea or China, which have been doubling their incomes every decade or quicker, the theory of catch-up seems reasonable. But many poor countries are growing more slowly than the developed countries and the gap is only increasing. The political system does matter when it comes to economic development. Economist Mancur Olson produced a remarkable and simple theory of why stable dictatorships should be worse for economic growth than democracies, but better than anarchies. A leader who needs to secure broader support for his policies will need to spend more government revenues on wealth-creating goods and services like roads and courts, and less on himself and his cronies. The greater the democratic pressures, the more healthy the economy is likely to become. Any development project is most likely to be successful if the people who benefit from its success are the same people who make it possible. Unfortunately, in many cases, development projects are often commissioned by people with less interest in success and more in bribes and career advancement. If the effectiveness of the project is a minor consideration, then it can hardly be a surprise if the project does not deliver on the publicly announced aims, even if it has delivered on the real aims of enriching bureaucrats. And even if the project was one that would still have been commissioned if genuine development really was the goal, bribes and other distortions are likely to spoil things. Take the case of Cameroon, which the author has studied from close quarters. Cameroon’s education system would be better if people had an incentive to get a good education; if a meritocracy were in place, and good grades and real skills – rather than connections – earned jobs. Cameroon would have better technology and more working factories if the investment climate was right and if the profits weren’t eaten up by bribes. The small amount of education and technology and infrastructure that Cameroon does have could be much better used if the society was organised to reward good productive ideas. But in Cameroon, this simply does not happen. To illustrate, there is no point investing in a business because the government will not protect you against thieves. There’s no point in paying the phone bill because nobody can successfully take you to court. There’s no point getting an education because jobs are not handed out on merit. There’s no point setting up an import business because the customs officers will be the ones to benefit. 10 Trade & the MNCs MNCs have been extensively blamed for creating sweatshops in poor countries. But workers go there voluntarily, which means that other alternatives are worse. They stay there, too. Turnover rates of multinational – owned factories are low, because conditions and pay, while bad, are better than those in factories run by local firms. And a job is better than options like: running an illegal street stall, working as a prostitute or searching through landfills to find recyclable goods. Free trade destroys the scarcity power of big firms by subjecting them to international competition. It encourages the use of new ways of working and better technology. Some people even think it promotes peace by giving trading nations powerful reasons not to go to war with each other. It is often the special-interest groups with disproportionate influence, not the common man, that have reasons to oppose free trade. Tariffs The benefits of tariffs are substantial for a narrowly concentrated group of people, often sectors with organized unions and large businesses. If voters are well informed, the protectionists will be voted down. But if people are not well informed, tariffs may remain especially if the campaign for trade restriction is discussed as a campaign against sweatshops. Reform efforts may also be stymied by inertia and nervousness on the part of these poorly informed voters, while the special interest groups are well aware that they stand to gain from protection and find it worthwhile to invest in lobbying efforts to defend their narrow interests. In a healthy democracy, special interests should have less power than in a fragile democracy or an undemocratic country, like Cameroon. If special-interest groups are part of the explanation behind trade barriers, countries with better-established democracies should have lower trade barriers. No political system is perfect, but democracies tend to favour trade more than others, because lowering trade barriers is good for the ordinary person. How China Grew Rich The author provides a fascinating account of the growth of China in recent years. Under Mao, China’s development efforts were two-pronged: massive investment in heavy industry such as steel, plus application of special agricultural techniques to increase good production. The policy took into account the availability of coal in China’s northern provinces and the fact that coal, steel and heavy manufacturing had been the basis of the industrial revolution in the United Kingdom, the United States and Germany. Increasing agricultural production was important because there was barely enough fertile land to feed the country’s hundreds of millions of people. 11 But this two-pronged push was the greatest economic failure the world has ever seen. Mao conducted economic policy on the hidden premise that if people tried hard, the impossible would happen. Villagers were ordered to build steel furnaces in their backyards but had no iron ore to put into them. Some villagers melted down good iron and steel – tools, even doorknobs – in order to meet the quotas demanded by the state. If industrial policy was a farce, agricultural policy was a tragedy. The Great Leap Forward had already pulled many workers off the land to labour at the furnaces or in public works like dams and roads. Mao ordered the people to kill grain-eating birds. The population of insect pests exploded as a result. Mao suggested closer planting and deeper sowing to increase yields. Rice planted so closely together could not grow, but party officials, anxious to please Mao, staged shows to demonstrate that the policies were succeeding. Mistakes can happen in market economies perhaps more frequently than under central planning. But the mistakes stay small. When venture capitalists back new ideas, they do not expect many to succeed. When a few of them succeed, they make some people rich and bring innovation to the whole economy. In case of the many ideas that fail, some people will go bankrupt, but nobody will die. Only command economies can promote experimentation on an extravagant scale, suppress informed criticism and continue economically unviable activities for too long. Mao’s successor, Deng was more pragmatic. He had little time for such folly and immediately embarked on a programme of reform, announcing that ‘socialism does not mean poverty’. To improve agriculture, he had to get the incentives right. He started by raising the price paid by the state for crops by nearly a quarter. The price paid for surplus crops rose by more than 40 per cent, substantially increasing the incentive for fertile areas to produce more crops. At the same time, a few collectives experimented with subcontracting land to individual households. Instead of clamping down, the government allowed the innovation to see whether it would make people work hard and find smarter ways of doing things because they were rewarded directly for their successes. Crop yields immediately increased. The experiment spread: just 1 per cent of collectives had used the ‘household responsibility system’ in 1979; by 1983, 98 per cent had switched to the system. Partly by accident, partly by benign neglect and partly by design, Deng introduced the market system to Chinese agriculture. Those who had good ideas, good luck and worked hard prospered. Farmers grew more cash crops and devoted less effort to crops that were difficult to grow. All of this was the result of introducing a price system. As late as 1992, only 14 percent of industrial output was being produced by privately owned or foreign firms, while the state sector was responsible for nearly half of the output. The output of local-government township and village enterprises made up most 12 of the remainder. The Chinese economic miracle was not really about privatization. What mattered was not who owned the companies. The companies were forced to compete in a relatively free market, driving down scarcity power and bringing in market forces. The Chinese reformers realized that engaging with the world could help. First, China could tap into world markets for labour-intensive goods; toys, shoes and clothes. Second, the foreign exchange earned could be spent on raw materials and on new technology to develop the economy. And foreign investors could help the locals learn modern production and business techniques. Conclusion Countries who want to prosper must accept the basic lessons of economics – embrace markets, fight scarcity power and corruption; correct externalities; try to maximize information; get the incentives right and engage with other countries. In the end, economics is about people. And economic growth is about a better life for individuals – more choice, less fear, less toil and hardship.
Docsity logo



Copyright © 2024 Ladybird Srl - Via Leonardo da Vinci 16, 10126, Torino, Italy - VAT 10816460017 - All rights reserved